This is the accessible text file for GAO report number GAO-07-97 
entitled 'Medicaid: Strategies to Help States Address Increased 
Expenditures during Economic Downturns' which was released on November 
15, 2007.

This text file was formatted by the U.S. Government Accountability 
Office (GAO) to be accessible to users with visual impairments, as part 
of a longer term project to improve GAO products' accessibility. Every 
attempt has been made to maintain the structural and data integrity of 
the original printed product. Accessibility features, such as text 
descriptions of tables, consecutively numbered footnotes placed at the 
end of the file, and the text of agency comment letters, are provided 
but may not exactly duplicate the presentation or format of the printed 
version. The portable document format (PDF) file is an exact electronic 
replica of the printed version. We welcome your feedback. Please E-mail 
your comments regarding the contents or accessibility features of this 
document to Webmaster@gao.gov.

This is a work of the U.S. government and is not subject to copyright 
protection in the United States. It may be reproduced and distributed 
in its entirety without further permission from GAO. Because this work 
may contain copyrighted images or other material, permission from the 
copyright holder may be necessary if you wish to reproduce this 
material separately.

United States Government Accountability Office: 
GAO:

Report to Congressional Requesters:

October 2006:

Medicaid: 
Strategies to Help States Address Increased Expenditures during 
Economic Downturns:

GAO-07-97:

GAO Highlights:

Highlights of GAO-07-97, a report to congressional requesters: 

Why GAO Did This Study:

During economic downturns, states may struggle to finance Medicaid, a 
federal-state health financing program for certain low-income 
individuals. States receive federal matching funds for their Medicaid 
programs according to a statutory formula based on each state's per 
capita income (PCI) in relation to national PCI. The number of 
individuals eligible for Medicaid can increase during downturns as a 
result of rising unemployment. GAO previously reported that any federal 
assistance to respond to downturns should be well-timed and account for 
each state’s fiscal circumstances. GAO was asked to consider strategies 
to help states offset increased Medicaid expenditures in the event of 
future economic downturns. 

GAO analyzed policy proposals and federal and state strategies to cope 
with downturns to identify and develop three potential strategies. GAO 
explored (1) targeting assistance to states most affected by a 
downturn, (2) using 2 instead of 3 years of PCI data to compute federal 
matching rates to more accurately reflect states’ economic 
circumstances, and (3) giving states the option to obtain assistance 
based on their own determination of need. GAO discussed the strategies 
with experts, identified design considerations, and analyzed each 
strategy’s potential effects.

The Department of Health and Human Services received a draft of this 
report and did not comment.

What GAO Found:

No single strategy or combination of strategies can meet the varied 
economic needs of all states at all times, but one or more of the 
following strategies GAO analyzed may be useful for Congress as it 
deliberates how to help states cope with Medicaid expenditure increases 
during economic downturns. Any potential strategy would need to be 
considered within the context of broader health care and fiscal 
challenges, including continually rising health care costs, a growing 
elderly population, and Medicaid’s increasing share of the federal 
budget.

Supplemental federal assistance provided to states based on changes in 
states’ unemployment rates would target funds to states most affected 
by downturns. GAO used unemployment as the key variable because it 
reflects the potential for increases in Medicaid enrollment resulting 
from an economic downturn. GAO created a simulation model to illustrate 
this strategy, which also adjusts the amount of funding relative to 
each state’s per person spending on Medicaid services. The model 
captured about 90 percent of states’ increases in unemployment during 
2001, and all states would have received some federal assistance. A few 
states with relatively earlier or later increases in unemployment would 
not have received a commensurate amount of funding because a portion of 
their downturns was outside the period of the simulation. 

Using 2 years of PCI data to compute federal matching rates instead of 
the 3 years required under current law did not result in matching rates 
that consistently reflected current economic circumstances, as measured 
by PCI or changes in states’ unemployment. Under certain conditions, 
reducing the number of years of data also skewed rates farther from 
current economic conditions. This strategy would also result in greater 
annual fluctuations in matching rates for most states. For these 
reasons, eliminating 1 year of PCI data is not a feasible alternative 
to help states address increased Medicaid expenditures.

States could be given the option to decide whether and to what extent 
they need federal assistance, through a loan, either from the federal 
government or from the private capital market (subsidized and possibly 
guaranteed by the federal government), or a Medicaid-specific national 
“rainy day” fund. This strategy’s viability would depend on states’ 
willingness to pay into a national fund or assume additional Medicaid-
specific debt and on states’ accepting the terms of the loan or rainy 
day fund. Federal funding required for this strategy would vary 
depending on design factors such as whether federal loan subsidies or 
Medicaid rainy day matching funds are included.

[hyperlink, http://www.gao.gov/cgi-bin/getrpt?GAO-07-97].

To view the full product, including the scope and methodology, click on 
the link above. For more information, contact Kathryn G. Allen at (202) 
512-7118 or Stanley J. Czerwinski at (202) 512-6806.

Contents:

Letter:

Results in Brief:

Background:

Targeting Supplemental Federal Assistance to States Requires Careful 
Consideration to Address Differences in States' Downturns:

Using Fewer Years of Data to Compute Matching Rates Would Not 
Consistently Result in Assistance that Better Reflects States' Current 
Economic Conditions:

States Could Determine Their Own Needs for Assistance with Medicaid- 
Specific Loans or a National Rainy Day Fund:

Concluding Observations:

Agency Comments:

Appendix I: Objectives, Scope, and Methodology:

Appendix II: Designing a Strategy of Targeted Supplemental Medicaid 
Assistance:

Appendix III: Designing a Strategy to Better Reflect States' Current 
Economic Conditions:

Appendix IV: Information on Selected Intergovernmental Loan Programs 
and State Rainy Day Funds:

Appendix V: GAO Contacts and Staff Acknowledgments:

Tables:

Table 1: Average Annual State Medicaid Expenditures per Beneficiary, by 
Population Group, 2003:

Table 2: Key Design Decisions, Parameters of GAO's Model, and 
Alternative Parameters that Could Be Applied for Targeting Supplemental 
Medicaid Assistance to States:

Table 3: Characteristics of Economic Downturns and Their Effect on 
States' Receipt of Supplemental Assistance:

Table 4: Analysis of Three Strategies to Help States Respond to 
Increased Medicaid Costs during Economic Downturns:

Table 5: Simulated Supplemental Assistance for Economic Conditions of 
the 2001 Downturn:

Table 6: Matching Rates Used to Analyze Strategy:

Table 7: Comparison of States' Year-to-Year Differences in 2-Year and 3-
Year Matching Rates, 1990-2004:

Figures:

Figure 1: Medicaid Beneficiaries and Expenditures by Population Group, 
Fiscal Year 2003:

Figure 2: States' Percentage Point Change in Unemployment, March 2001 
to March 2002:

Figure 3: Number of States Experiencing a 10 Percent or More Increase 
in Their Unemployment Rate, 2000 to 2004:

Figure 4: Timing of Data Used to Calculate States' Federal Matching 
Rates for Fiscal Year 2006:

Figure 5: Number of States with a 10 Percent or More Increase in Their 
Unemployment Rate Compared to the Same Quarter 1 Year Earlier, 1979- 
2004:

Figure 6: Total of States' Quarterly Increase in Unemployment Covered 
by Simulation Model's Supplemental Assistance:

Figure 7: Effects of Alternative Threshold Parameters on the Start and 
Number of Quarters of Supplemental Assistance, 2000 through 2005:

Figure 8: Simulated Supplemental Assistance for a State with an Early, 
Long, and Deep Economic Downturn:

Figure 9: Simulated Supplemental Assistance for a State with a 
Relatively Early, Long-Lasting, and Shallow Downturn:

Figure 10: Simulated Supplemental Assistance for a State with a Late, 
Short, and Shallow Downturn:

Figure 11: Simulated Supplemental Assistance for a State with a Short, 
Deep Downturn:

Figure 12: Correlations of the Changes in the 3-Year and 2-Year 
Matching Rates with Changes in PCI:

Figure 13: Correlations of the Changes in the 3-Year and 2-Year 
Matching Rates with Changes in the Unemployment Rates:

Figure 14: Correlations of the Changes in the Simulated Matching Rate 
with the Changes in PCI, 1990 to 2004:

Figure 15: Correlations of the Changes in 3-Year and 2-Year Matching 
Rates with the Changes in the Simulated Matching Rate:

Abbreviations:

BCCA: Breast and Cervical Cancer Act: 
BEA: Bureau of Economic Analysis: 
BLS: Bureau of Labor Statistics: 
CMS: Centers for Medicare & Medicaid Services: 
CWSRF: Clean Water State Revolving Fund: 
CDL: Community Disaster Loan: 
EPA: Environmental Protection Agency: 
FEMA: Federal Emergency Management Agency: 
FMAP: Federal Medical Assistance Percentage: 
FUA: Federal Unemployment Account: 
GDP: gross domestic product: 
JGTRRA: Jobs and Growth Tax Relief Reconciliation Act of 2003: 
NASBO: National Association of State Budget Officers: 
NBER: National Bureau of Economic Research: 
NCSL: National Conference of State Legislatures: 
PCI: per capita income: 
TANF: Temporary Assistance for Needy Families: 
UI: Unemployment Insurance: 

[End of section]

United States Government Accountability Office: Washington, DC 20548:

October 18, 2006:

The Honorable Susan M. Collins: 
Chairman: 
Committee on Homeland Security 
and Governmental Affairs: 
United States Senate:

The Honorable Gordon H. Smith: 
Chairman: 
Special Committee on Aging: 
United States Senate:

The Honorable Jeff Bingaman: 
The Honorable Ben Nelson: 
The Honorable John D. Rockefeller, IV: United States Senate:

During economic downturns, states can experience difficulties financing 
programs such as Medicaid, a joint federal-state health financing 
program that covers medical costs for certain categories of low-income 
individuals. Economic downturns result in rising unemployment, which 
can lead to increases in the number of individuals who are eligible for 
Medicaid coverage, and in declining tax revenues, which can lead to 
less available revenue with which to fund coverage of additional 
enrollees. For example, during a period of economic downturn, Medicaid 
enrollment rose 8.6 percent between 2001 and 2002, which was largely 
attributed to states' increases in unemployment. During this same time 
period, state tax revenues fell 7.5 percent. Further complicating the 
challenge of responding to increased Medicaid expenditures during 
economic downturns is the fact that Medicaid funding consumed a growing 
share of state general fund or operating budgets, increasing from 15 
percent in 1994 to 18 percent in 2004.:

Both the federal government and the states have responded to the 
demands of Medicaid expenditure increases related to economic 
downturns. Following the 2001 recession, Congress passed the Jobs and 
Growth Tax Relief Reconciliation Act of 2003 (JGTRRA), which provided 
$10 billion in fiscal relief through a temporary increase in federal 
Medicaid funding for all states, as well as $10 billion in general 
assistance divided among the states to be used for essential government 
services. States have responded to downturns in various ways, such as 
by using cost-cutting program modifications; budget stabilization, or 
"rainy day," funds; and borrowing.

Problems that states face in financing Medicaid cost increases during 
an economic downturn can be exacerbated because, by design, the formula 
used to calculate the amount of federal assistance that states receive 
for Medicaid includes data that are as much as 5 years old. The federal 
government matches state Medicaid spending according to this formula, 
which is based on each state's per capita income (PCI) in relation to 
national PCI. The amount of federal assistance states receive for 
Medicaid is determined by a statutory formula known as the Federal 
Medical Assistance Percentage (FMAP), or federal matching rate. The 
statute specifies that matching rates be calculated 1 year before the 
fiscal year in which they are effective, using a 3-year average of the 
most recently available PCI data reported by the Department of 
Commerce. For example, fiscal year 2007 matching rates were calculated 
at the beginning of fiscal year 2006 using a 3-year average of PCI for 
2002 through 2004. Consequently, federal matching rates reflect 
economic conditions that existed several years earlier.

Recognizing the complex combination of factors affecting states during 
economic downturns--increased unemployment, declining state revenues, 
and increased downturn-related Medicaid costs--policymakers and others 
have considered the possibility of establishing a legislative response 
that would help states better cope with Medicaid cost increases. Any 
potential legislative response would need to be considered within the 
context of broader health care and fiscal challenges--including 
continually rising health care costs, a growing elderly population, and 
Medicare and Medicaid's increasing share of the federal budget. Absent 
fundamental Medicaid reform, legislative actions and proposals have 
generally focused on targeting assistance to states, improving the 
timing of the assistance provided, or helping states build financial 
reserves for Medicaid.:

In 2004, we reported on the assistance provided by the federal 
government to the states through JGTRRA, noting that federal assistance 
is most effective when it takes into account each state's fiscal 
circumstances as well as when and how severely states are affected by 
an economic downturn. On the basis of these findings, you asked us to 
consider strategies to help states address the increased costs of 
Medicaid in any future economic downturn. An underlying assumption was 
that, in the event of any future nationwide economic downturn, Congress 
would act to appropriate additional funds, as it did following the 2001 
recession. Your interest was in exploring strategies whereby any 
additional funds could be accurately timed and targeted to respond to a 
downturn but could also be established in advance so that Congress 
would not have to wait to act until a nationwide economic downturn is 
clearly identified. Accordingly, we reviewed prior GAO reports, policy 
proposals, and federal and state strategies to cope with downturns to 
identify and develop three potential strategies. In this report, we 
explore the design considerations and possible effects of three 
potential strategies aimed at helping states with their share of 
Medicaid expenditures during an economic downturn by (1) targeting 
supplemental funds to specific states on the basis of the relative 
depth and duration of their economic downturns (as measured by changes 
in their unemployment rates) as well as the extent to which their 
Medicaid costs are likely to increase during a downturn, (2) using 2 
instead of 3 years of PCI data to compute federal matching rates in an 
attempt to better reflect states' current economic conditions, and (3) 
providing states with options for obtaining assistance through a 
Medicaid-specific rainy day fund or loan based on their own 
determination of need.

To do our work, we analyzed research, including prior GAO reports that 
examined the effects of economic downturns on Medicaid enrollment and 
expenditures, the responsiveness of federal matching rates to economic 
cycles, and policy proposals to help states respond to increased 
program costs during downturns. We discussed the three potential 
strategies with technical experts and representatives of key research 
groups and state associations to gain insights on the extent to which 
strategies could help states cope with the Medicaid-related fiscal 
consequences of economic downturns. These discussions provided an 
opportunity to evaluate our selection of strategies and discuss their 
potential effects. Our analysis of the strategies differed depending on 
the strategy. For the first strategy, we identified factors to consider 
in developing the targeting strategy and devised a model to illustrate 
the extent to which different methods of targeting supplemental federal 
funds would help states with their Medicaid programs during economic 
downturns. The assumptions built into our model were based on our 
analysis of data indicators from the past three recessions. We chose 
unemployment as the key variable because it reflects the potential for 
increases in Medicaid enrollments as a result of an economic downturn. 
For the second strategy, which focused on using 2 years of PCI data-- 
instead of the 3 years currently required by statute--to compute 
federal matching rates in an attempt to better reflect states' economic 
conditions, we analyzed how closely the federal matching rates 
approximated states' economic conditions and constructed statistical 
simulations to compare the federal assistance states would receive 
under the strategy with the assistance they would receive under current 
policy. To determine the potential of each of the first two strategies 
to help states address increased Medicaid spending, we simulated how 
the implementation of the strategy could differ depending on the 
timing, depth, and duration of a state's economic downturn. For the 
third strategy, which focused on providing states with options for 
obtaining assistance through a Medicaid-specific national rainy day 
fund or loan, we identified key factors that could be considered, such 
as the structure and use of existing intergovernmental loan programs 
and state rainy day funds. We determined that the unemployment, PCI, 
and Medicaid expenditure data used in this report are sufficiently 
reliable for describing the three strategies and illustrating their 
potential effects. (Appendixes I through IV provide additional detail 
about our methodology for assessing the three strategies.) We did our 
work from April 2005 through September 2006 in accordance with 
generally accepted government auditing standards.

Results in Brief:

No single strategy or combination of strategies can meet the varied 
economic needs of all states at all times. However, the following 
strategies may be useful starting points for Congress as it deliberates 
how to help states cope with increased Medicaid expenditures during any 
future economic downturn. Having an automatic mechanism in place could 
provide a targeted and predictable response. The three strategies we 
explored are:

* target supplemental Medicaid assistance to states most affected by a 
downturn,

* use 2 years of PCI data to compute federal matching rates in an 
effort to better reflect states' current economic circumstances, and:

* give states the option to obtain assistance through a Medicaid- 
specific national rainy day fund or loan.

First, a strategy that provides supplemental assistance to states based 
on changes in their unemployment rates would target funds to states 
most affected by a downturn, but the design of such a strategy would 
need to address the different characteristics of states' downturns. To 
illustrate this strategy, we constructed a simulation model that 
adjusts the amount of funding a state would receive on the basis of 
each state's percentage increases in unemployment and per person 
spending on Medicaid services. Our simulation model captured about 90 
percent of states' increases in unemployment during the most recent 
(2001) recession. While all states received some amount of assistance 
under the model, states that experienced the largest percentage 
increases in unemployment within the same period in which the national 
downturn occurred received the largest proportion of supplemental 
assistance. A smaller number of states received less assistance than 
others in our simulation model because their increased unemployment 
occurred either earlier or later than the national downturn. 
Adjustments to the strategy design, such as extending the period of 
assistance, could be applied to ensure that states with earlier or 
later increases in unemployment also receive a commensurate amount of 
funding, but such adjustments would add to the overall cost of the 
strategy. Targeted supplemental federal assistance to states most 
affected by a downturn could assist states relative to the depth and 
duration of a downturn as well as increased Medicaid expenditures while 
also reflecting congressional policy choices.

Second, using 2 years of PCI data to compute federal matching rates 
instead of the 3 years required under current law did not result in 
matching rates that consistently reflected states' recent economic 
circumstances as measured by PCI or changes in states' unemployment. To 
illustrate this strategy, we analyzed matching rates that varied in the 
number of years of data used and compared them with changes in PCI and 
unemployment data. Our analysis of this strategy, however, did not 
result in federal matching rates that consistently increased during 
economic downturns. In some cases, reducing the number of years of data 
also skewed rates farther away from current economic conditions. In 
addition, this strategy would result in larger year-to-year changes in 
matching rates for most states compared to the fluctuations experienced 
under current law. For these reasons, eliminating a year of data from 
the current matching formula does not present a feasible alternative to 
help states address increased Medicaid expenditures during economic 
downturns.

Third, giving states the opportunity to decide whether and to what 
extent they need federal assistance could take the form of a loan, 
either from the federal government or from the private capital market 
(subsidized and possibly guaranteed by the federal government), or a 
Medicaid-specific national rainy day fund. A federal Medicaid loan or 
rainy day fund could give states greater autonomy in determining their 
need for assistance, but utilization of either approach would depend on 
states' own economic and political constraints as well as the program's 
design. For example, limitations on the use of a loan may exist because 
of a state's statutory or constitutional debt restrictions as well as 
federal restrictions on the obligation of federal funds. While a 
national rainy day fund could allow states to pool their risk and 
thereby spend less than they would if they chose to establish 
individual Medicaid rainy day funds at the state level, representatives 
of some public policy and research organizations we contacted believed 
that some states might be reluctant to contribute to a national fund 
that other states or the federal government could draw from. Federal 
funding required for this strategy would vary depending on design 
factors such as the inclusion of federal subsidies or matching funds. A 
loan or national rainy day fund strategy could help address states' 
Medicaid funding challenges during downturns, but the feasibility and 
utility of this strategy would depend on the design of the loan or 
fund, among other possible constraints.

Background:

Economic downturns are characterized by reductions in output and income 
as well as increased unemployment--and an accompanying increase in 
Medicaid enrollment. Generally, as unemployment rises, the number of 
households with incomes low enough to qualify for Medicaid coverage 
also rises. Across the four broad populations eligible for Medicaid-- 
children; nondisabled, nonelderly adults; the elderly; and individuals 
with disabilities--increases in eligibility for Medicaid during an 
economic downturn are most concentrated among children and nondisabled, 
nonelderly adults. One analysis of the relationship between 
unemployment and Medicaid enrollment found that a 1 percentage point 
increase in the unemployment rate would result in a nationwide increase 
in Medicaid enrollment of more than 857,000 individuals--about 470,000 
children and 387,000 nondisabled, nonelderly adults. While these two 
populations make up the largest share of Medicaid beneficiaries, they 
represent a small share of total Medicaid expenditures (see fig. 1). 
Nondisabled, nonelderly adults and children make up 76 percent of 
beneficiaries but account for just 30 percent of expenditures. 
[Footnote 11]

Figure 1: Medicaid Beneficiaries and Expenditures by Population Group, 
Fiscal Year 2003:

This figure depicts two pie charts showing beneficiaries and 
expenditures.

Beneficiaries (48.2 million):
Children and nondisabled, nonelderly adults: 76%; Aged: 8%; Blind and 
disabled: 16%.

Expenditures ($223.8 billion):
Children and nondisabled, nonelderly adults: 30%; Aged: 25%; Blind and 
disabled: 45%.

[See PDF for image]

Source: GAO analysis of CMS data. 

Note: Percentages are based on Centers for Medicare & Medicaid Services 
(CMS) beneficiary and expenditure data for fiscal year 2003, the most 
recent year for which data are available by type of beneficiary. Total 
fiscal year 2003 expenditures for Medicaid were $276 billion. 
Expenditures in figure 1 do not include administrative expenses, 
disproportionate share hospital payments, and other expenses that could 
not be attributed to specific beneficiary populations. Beneficiaries do 
not include women covered under the Breast and Cervical Cancer Act 
(BCCA) or individuals whose eligibility status is unknown.

[End of figure]

Additionally, increases in Medicaid enrollment and expenditures that 
occur during nationwide downturns are not distributed evenly among 
states because of differences in states' economic conditions, Medicaid 
program design, and health care costs. Among states, downturns vary 
widely in their onset, depth, and duration. For example, in March 2001, 
the United States entered a recession, as indicated by a significant 
decline in overall business activity, including an increase in 
unemployment, over several months. During the next year, the national 
unemployment rate increased by 1.4 percentage points, from 4.3 percent 
to 5.7 percent. During this same period, the unemployment rate 
increased by more than 2 percentage points in some states but actually 
decreased in others (see fig. 2).

Figure 2: States' Percentage Point Change in Unemployment, March 2001 
to March 2002:

This is a map of the United States with states shaded according to 
percentage point change in five categories:
-0.5 to 0.1; 
0.2 to 0.8; 
0.9 to 1.5; 
1.6 to 2.2; 
2.3 to 2.9.

[See PDF for image]

Source: GAO. 

Note: Percentage point unemployment changes from GAO, Health Insurance: 
States' Protections and Programs Benefit Some Unemployed Individuals, 
GAO-03-191 (Washington, D.C.: Oct. 25, 2002).

[End of figure]

The Medicaid enrollment and expenditure increases associated with a 
given increase in unemployment also vary across states because of 
differences in the scope of states' coverage for groups most affected 
by the downturn. For example, in 2003, average annual state 
expenditures for children and nondisabled, nonelderly adults ranged 
from $1,258 per beneficiary to $4,377, with a national average of 
$1,823. Table 1 shows the range in states' Medicaid expenditures per 
beneficiary by population group in 2003.

Table 1: Average Annual State Medicaid Expenditures per Beneficiary, by 
Population Group, 2003:

State Medicaid expenditures: Average; 
Children and nondisabled, nonelderly adults: $1,823; 
Elderly: $14,540; Blind/disabled: $14,079.

State Medicaid expenditures: Minimum; 
Children and nondisabled, nonelderly adults: 1,258; 
Elderly: 6,781; Blind/disabled: 6,792.

State Medicaid expenditures: Maximum; 
Children and nondisabled, nonelderly adults: 4,377; 
Elderly: 26,384; Blind/disabled: 25,553.

Source: GAO analysis of CMS data.

Note: Data represent annual state expenditures per beneficiary.

[End of table] 

The federal matching formula for Medicaid adjusts for differences in 
state fiscal capacity and reduces program benefit disparities across 
states by providing more federal funds to states with weaker tax bases 
[Footnote 13]. The statutory matching formula calculates the federal 
matching rate for each state on the basis of its PCI in relation to 
national PCI as follows.

Federal matching rate = 1.00 - 0.45*[(State PCI) / (U.S. PCI)]2:

Relative PCI is included as a representation of states' funding 
ability, as a combination of states' resources and people in poverty. 
Squaring PCI has the effect of making PCI appear in the formula twice, 
to reflect both states' resources and people in poverty. The formula 
uses a 3-year average of PCI, the effect of which is to smooth out 
fluctuations in state PCI so that it reflects longer-term trends rather 
than short-term fluctuations of the business cycle. This smoothing 
effect helps minimize year-to-year changes in federal matching funds, 
which could be disruptive to states' budget planning.

The use of PCI as a measure of states' funding ability, however, is 
problematic. Our prior work concluded that PCI is not a comprehensive 
indicator of states' total available resources and thus does not 
accurately represent states' funding ability. PCI also does not account 
for the size and cost of serving states' poverty populations, which 
vary considerably; for example, two states with low PCIs may have very 
different proportions of elderly persons potentially eligible for 
Medicaid and thus very different amounts of Medicaid spending. 
Moreover, concerns have been raised regarding the age of the data used 
to calculate the matching rate. In particular, the use of a 3-year PCI 
average to compute matching rates, combined with a 1-year lag between 
computation and implementation, means that the rates reflect economic 
conditions that existed several years earlier.[Footnote 14]

To cope with the difficulties of financing Medicaid and other programs 
during an economic downturn, states have, among other actions, borrowed 
from intergovernmental loan programs and drawn down state budget 
stabilization funds, which are also referred to as rainy day funds. 
Intergovernmental loan programs can generally be categorized as direct 
loans or loan guarantees. Both require federal involvement and can 
include a federal subsidy, but loan guarantees are administered by 
nonfederal lending institutions. Federal credit programs can vary in 
their design and purpose. While federal guidelines offer broad 
standards and principles for administering credit programs, specific 
loan terms are set in statute or by administering agencies based on the 
program's policy goals[Footnote 15]. According to the National 
Association of State Budget Officers (NASBO), budget stabilization 
funds exist in almost all states and allow states to set aside surplus 
revenue during periods of economic growth for use during downturns. 
States have different legislative requirements regarding the amount of 
funds that can be accumulated, the process for releasing funds, and the 
purposes for which funds can be used.

Targeting Supplemental Federal Assistance to States Requires Careful 
Consideration to Address Differences in States' Downturns:

Providing supplemental federal assistance to states that is based on 
changes in their unemployment rates would target additional Medicaid 
funds to states most affected by a downturn, but the design of such a 
strategy would need to address the different characteristics of states' 
downturns. A strategy to target funds to states based on the duration 
and depth of states' downturns assumes that, if authorized by Congress, 
supplemental assistance could begin when predetermined thresholds are 
reached. This approach is in contrast with the 2003 fiscal relief 
package, JGTRRA, which provided assistance to states after the 
recession had ended. This supplemental assistance strategy would leave 
the existing Medicaid formula unchanged and add a new, separate 
assistance formula that would operate only during times of economic 
downturn and use variables and a distribution mechanism that differ 
from those used for calculating matching rates. We identified key 
design considerations for a strategy that would target funds based on 
states' downturns and devised a model to illustrate the extent to which 
it could help target supplemental federal Medicaid funds to states 
experiencing economic downturns of different depths and durations. The 
design we simulated in our model would deliver the most assistance to 
the group of states that experience increases in unemployment within 
the same relative period of time. However, a smaller number of states 
with relatively earlier or later increases in unemployment would 
receive less assistance. Further adjustments to the strategy design, 
such as methods to extend the period of assistance, could be applied to 
ensure that states with earlier or later increases in unemployment 
would receive more quarters of supplemental assistance payments. Such 
extensions, however, would add to the overall cost of the strategy.

Design Considerations:

Development of a strategy to target funds based on differences in 
states' economic downturns involves three key considerations: (1) 
deciding the starting and ending points of assistance, (2) determining 
the amount of additional federal Medicaid assistance that will be 
available, and (3) determining how this additional assistance will be 
distributed to the states. Using data from the past three recessions, 
we developed a model to simulate targeted supplemental assistance to 
states experiencing increased unemployment. The model focused on 
mechanisms to distribute supplemental federal funds depending on the 
extent of a state's downturn and its relative Medicaid expenditures.

To determine the amount of federal assistance that would be provided 
based on this strategy, our model incorporated a retrospective 
assessment, which would involve assessing the increase in each state's 
unemployment rate for a particular quarter compared to the same quarter 
of the previous year. The economic trigger for this strategy would be 
when 23 or more states had increased unemployment of 10 percent or more 
compared to the unemployment rate that existed for the same quarter 1 
year earlier (such as from 5 percent to 5.5 percent unemployment). This 
is an increase of 10 percent compared to the unemployment rate of the 
same quarter in the previous year and not a 10 percentage point change 
in unemployment rates (such as from 5 percent unemployment to 15 
percent). We chose these two threshold values--23 or more states and 
increased unemployment of 10 percent or more--to work in tandem to 
ensure that the national economy had entered a downturn and that the 
majority of states were not yet in recovery from the downturn [Footnote 
16]. Table 2 summarizes the key design decisions, our model's 
parameters, and some alternative parameters. (See app. II for 
additional discussion of the key design decisions incorporated into the 
GAO model.)

Table 2: Key Design Decisions, Parameters of GAO's Model, and 
Alternative Parameters that Could Be Applied for Targeting Supplemental 
Medicaid Assistance to States:

Key design decision: Establish starting and ending point; 
Parameters of GAO model[A]: Starting point; 
* The starting point would be when 23 or more states show a quarterly 
state unemployment rate increase of 10 percent or more (the 
retrospective assessment).[C]; 
* Once started, any state with any increase in unemployment would be 
eligible to receive assistance; Alternative parameters[B]: Starting 
point; 
* Varying numbers of states and percentage changes in unemployment 
could be applied; 
* Indicators other than unemployment--or indicators used in conjunction 
with unemployment--could be used to start the program; 
* Congressional action could be required to start the program (rather 
than establishing an automatic trigger based on threshold values).

Key design decision: Establish starting and ending point; 
Parameters of GAO model[A]: Ending point; 
* The ending point would be when fewer than 23 states had quarterly 
unemployment increases of 10 percent or more; 
* The number of quarters that assistance continued would depend on the 
severity and duration of the economic downturn; Alternative 
parameters[B]: Ending point; 
* Varying numbers of states, percentage changes in unemployment, and 
quarters of assistance could be applied; 
* Other indicators could be used to end the program; 
* Congressional action could be required to end the program (rather 
than establishing an automatic stopping point based on threshold 
values).

Key design decision: Determine amount of federal assistance to be 
available; 
Parameters of GAO model[A]: 
* The amount of federal assistance would be determined on the basis of 
the relationship between changes in unemployment and increases in 
Medicaid expenditures; 
* Based on the depth of the 2001 recession, the amount of federal 
assistance would have been $4.2 billion; Alternative parameters[B]: 
* The amount of federal assistance could be set by Congress based on 
factors other than changes in unemployment and increases in Medicaid 
expenditures.

Key design decision: Determine distribution of assistance; 
Parameters of GAO model[A]: 
* Funds would be distributed quarterly through a targeted supplement to 
states' federal matching rates; 
* Distribution amount varies based on a state's change in unemployment 
and its average cost of providing services to children and nondisabled, 
nonelderly adults; Alternative parameters[B]: 
* Model could allow for a lump-sum grant distributed on some schedule 
other than quarterly payments tied to states' federal matching rates; 
* Retroactive rebate payments could be provided to the states based on 
their actual increased expenditures; 
* Assistance could be determined based on an alternative threshold 
(other than a 10 percent or more increase in unemployment).

Source: GAO.

[A] Our model assumed that once enacted, the targeted assistance would 
operate without the need for congressional action to initiate 
assistance during an economic downturn.

[B] Most alternative parameters were not simulated in our model. 
Appendix II provides additional details on alternative parameters that 
could be used.

[C] The retrospective assessment is based on a quarterly moving average 
of seasonally adjusted unemployment data for the 12 most recent months. 
The GAO model included these parameters based on quantitative analysis 
of prior recessions combined with subjective judgment. We chose these 
threshold values based on evidence which indicated that 23 states 
experiencing a 10 percent or more increase in unemployment provided 
considerable certainty that an economic slowdown had extended 
nationwide and that at least 23 states had not yet entered a recovery. 
These parameters could be adjusted up or down to tighten or loosen the 
threshold for providing supplemental assistance. The use of 
unemployment as an indicator also reflects research establishing a 
connection between increased unemployment and Medicaid enrollment.

[End of table]

To determine the amount of supplemental federal assistance needed to 
help states address increased Medicaid expenditures during a downturn, 
we relied on research that estimated a relationship between changes in 
unemployment and changes in Medicaid spending while holding constant 
other factors that influence Medicaid spending[Footnote 17] . Using 
data from the 2001 and the 1991-1992 recessions and this research, our 
model assumes federal assistance of approximately $4.2 billion, which 
would be less than 1 percent of Medicaid spending for a 2-year 
period[Footnote18]. Depending on the fund distribution method, 
budgeting sufficient amounts for the supplemental federal funding would 
require estimating the potential economic effects of a downturn because 
forecasting states' unemployment increases is difficult. If the 
targeting strategy was designed to function as an open-ended grant that 
provides states with an incremental increase to their matching rates, 
then states' expenditures would be matched as the downturn-induced 
growth of enrollments increased their Medicaid spending. However, if 
the program was designed to provide a lump-sum amount of assistance or 
to function as a closed-ended assistance program, then setting a 
funding level would be necessary.

Within the key parameters that frame this strategy are many variations 
in design that could be considered to achieve different policy goals. 
For example, if it was deemed important to provide states with a longer 
period of assistance, the retrospective assessment of the increase in 
the unemployment rate could be extended in order to help states with 
longer-lasting or late downturns. Additional criteria could be 
established to accomplish other policy objectives, such as controlling 
federal spending by limiting the number of quarters of payments or 
stopping payments after predetermined spending caps are reached.

Effects:

Our simulation model showed that a retrospective assessment resulting 
in a 10 percent or more increase in unemployment in 23 or more states 
would trigger supplemental assistance for 7 quarters, the period 
beginning with the first quarter of 2002 and continuing through the 
third quarter of 2003. Overall, about 90 percent of state increases in 
unemployment from the second quarter of 2000 through the fourth quarter 
of 2004 were captured by our simulation, which began the assistance in 
the first quarter of 2002 and continued it through the third quarter of 
2003[Footnote 19]. If the simulation model had been in effect during 
the 2001 recession, this strategy's starting point would have provided 
assistance to states a full year earlier than the enhanced matching 
rate implemented by Congress under the previous fiscal assistance 
legislation, JGTRRA, which began providing supplemental assistance in 
the third quarter of 2003. (See fig. 3.)

Figure 3: Number of States Experiencing a 10 Percent or More Increase 
in Their Unemployment Rate, 2000 to 2004:

This is a vertical bar graph with bars representing the number of 
states experiencing the increase per quarter. The vertical axis 
represents Number of states, from 0 to 50. The horizontal axis 
represents yearly quarters from year 2000 through year 2004. 

[See PDF for image]

[A] 2002, first quarter: The quarter in which payment begins under this 
strategy reflects a two-quarter lag for data to become available. 
Therefore, the count of states represents the count from the third 
quarter of 2001.

[B] 2003, third quarter: In response to the 2001 recession, our model 
would have had the strategy in operation from the first quarter of 2002 
to the third quarter of 2003, the period when 23 states had a 10 
percent or more increase in unemployment compared to the same quarter 
of the previous year.

[C] Quarters: For comparison purposes, the enhanced matching rate under 
the 2003 fiscal relief package, JGTRRA, was implemented in the third 
quarter of 2003.

[End of figure]

Under this strategy, our model's results show that the timing and depth 
of a state's economic downturn can affect the amount of supplemental 
assistance a state receives. In general, states with deep downturns 
that occur coincident with the period in which supplemental assistance 
payments would be made would receive the largest proportion of federal 
assistance. States experiencing an earlier or later economic downturn-
-meaning more than 1 year before or 1 year later than the start of the 
payments--would not receive payments to cover the full period of their 
economic downturn, regardless of the extent of the state's increased 
unemployment. With regard to the depth of each state's downturn, the 
results of our model simulation showed that all states would receive 
some amount of supplemental federal Medicaid assistance, with the 
increased matching rate ranging from 0 percent to 2.01 percent[Footnote 
20]. (See table 3.) In contrast, the previous fiscal assistance 
legislation, JGTRRA, provided the same matching rate increase to all 
states.

Table 3: Characteristics of Economic Downturns and Their Effect on 
States' Receipt of Supplemental Assistance:

Downturn characteristic: Timing; 
Effect on states' receipt of supplemental assistance: States with 
unemployment increases that are relatively earlier or later than the 
strategy's starting point may not receive the maximum amount of 
supplemental federal assistance; 
Results of GAO model[A]: 37 states would have had increases in 
unemployment commensurate with the start of the supplemental federal 
assistance; 12 states would have had increases in unemployment that 
began before the start of supplemental federal assistance; 1 state 
would have had an increase in unemployment that started after the 
supplemental federal assistance ended.

Downturn characteristic: Duration; 
Effect on states' receipt of supplemental assistance: States with 
economic downturns lasting 7 or fewer quarters would be most likely to 
receive the maximum amount of supplemental federal assistance; 
Results of GAO model[A]: 4 states had downturns lasting 7 quarters; 28 
states had downturns lasting fewer than 7 quarters.[B]; 18 states had 
downturns lasting more than 7 quarters.

Downturn characteristic: Depth; 
Effect on states' receipt of supplemental assistance: The supplemental 
federal assistance a state would receive is determined in part by the 
depth of its economic downturn and the amount of its unemployment 
increase; 
Results of GAO model[A]: 0.80 percent was the median increase in a 
state's federal matching rate; 0.00 percent was the lowest increase in 
a state's federal matching rate.[C]; 1.77 percent was the highest 
increase in a state's federal matching rate.

Source: GAO simulation using data from BLS and CMS.

[A] Based on the first quarter of 2002 through the third quarter of 
2003.

[B] One state showed no indication of a downturn based on increases in 
unemployment.

[C] One state received a matching rate increase that was less than 
0.005 percentage points.

[End of table]

Additionally, assistance provided to individual states would vary 
depending on the relative size and composition of their expenditures 
for cyclically sensitive Medicaid populations. Because economic 
downturns are likely to increase Medicaid enrollment for children and 
nondisabled, nonelderly adults--but generally not for the elderly or 
individuals with disabilities--we adjusted the amount of supplemental 
federal Medicaid assistance based on the characteristics of each 
state's Medicaid spending by beneficiary population category in order 
to target the amount of supplemental federal assistance. As a result, 
two states with similar downturns in terms of percentage change in 
unemployment could receive different amounts of supplemental assistance 
depending on their average cyclically sensitive Medicaid expenditures 
per nonelderly person in poverty. For example, Arizona and Wisconsin 
had an average quarterly percentage change in unemployment of 41 
percent and 52 percent during the 2001 recession, which would have 
resulted in lump sum amounts of assistance of $86 million and $106 
million, respectively. However, applying a Medicaid expenditure index 
that we developed, which takes into account each state's relative 
Medicaid spending per nonelderly person in poverty, Arizona would have 
received $93 million in supplemental federal Medicaid payments compared 
with $45 million for Wisconsin using the parameters described for this 
strategy.[Footnote 21]

Using Fewer Years of Data to Compute Matching Rates Would Not 
Consistently Result in Assistance that Better Reflects States' Current 
Economic Conditions:

A second strategy uses fewer years of data by eliminating the oldest 
data from the computation of federal matching rates in an attempt to 
better reflect states' current economic conditions. However, based on 
our analysis of a 15-year period (1990 to 2004), we found that using 
fewer years of data did not result in federal matching rates that 
better reflected states' current economic conditions. In particular, 
the inherent time lag necessary to obtain data and calculate the 
matching rates limited the ability of this strategy to provide 
assistance to states that reflected more recent economic conditions. In 
some cases, reducing the number of years of data skewed rates farther 
away from current economic conditions. This strategy would result in 
larger year-to-year changes in matching rates for most states compared 
with the fluctuations experienced under current law[Footnote22]. Based 
on this analysis, eliminating a year of data from the current matching 
formula would not help states address increased Medicaid expenditures 
during economic downturns.

Design Considerations:

This strategy would use fewer years of PCI data to compute federal 
matching rates. This strategy relies on the current matching formula, 
with the adjustment of using 2 years of PCI data instead of the 3 years 
required under current law (see fig. 4). Implementation of this 
strategy would require a statutory change to the federal matching 
formula and could be made permanent. Unlike the first strategy, which 
would require that an established number of states reach a certain 
percentage change in unemployment, this strategy would not require 
monitoring of economic conditions to trigger implementation. In 
addition, this strategy would not distribute the supplemental Medicaid 
assistance required for implementation of the first strategy but would 
instead adjust the relative proportion of Medicaid funding distributed 
to the states.

Figure 4: Timing of Data Used to Calculate States' Federal Matching 
Rates for Fiscal Year 2006:

2001[a], 2002, 2003: Average of PCI data from these 3 fiscal years 
included in fiscal year 2006 matching rate; October 2004: Department of 
Health and Human Services calculates and publishes matching rates for 
fiscal year 2006; October 2005: Fiscal year 2006 Medicaid matching 
rates become effective in October 2005 and remain in place through 
September 2006. 

Source: GAO. 

[See PDF for image]

[A] Under this strategy, 2001 data would be eliminated from the 
matching rate calculation.

[End of figure]

To analyze the effect of using fewer years of data to calculate the 
matching rates, we used three matching rates that employed the current 
statutory formula but varied in the years of data used. The first 
matching rate mirrored the current statutory construction, using 3 
years of PCI data that are 3 to 5 years old. The second matching rate 
was based on the statutory construction, except that it eliminated the 
oldest year of PCI data and only used 2 years of data. The third 
matching rate used PCI data for the current year (the year in which the 
calculations are made) and for 1 year prior, thus showing no time lag 
in the data used [Footnote 23]. We compared the three matching rates 
with year-to-year percentage changes in PCI and year-to-year percentage 
changes in the unemployment rate and analyzed the extent to which the 3-
year and 2-year matching rates fluctuated from year to year. (Appendix 
III provides additional detail regarding our methodology.)

Effects:

Contrary to our expectations that eliminating the oldest year of data 
from the computation of matching rates would make them more sensitive 
to current economic conditions, our simulation results showed that 
using 2 years of PCI data instead of 3 did not consistently improve the 
correlation of the rates with state PCI--one measure of state economic 
conditions. In addition, rates based on 2 years of PCI data did not 
result in rates that more closely correlated with states' PCI trends. 
We repeated the same analysis using unemployment data and confirmed 
that matching rates also did not correlate with state unemployment 
trends. These results remained consistent during the full period of our 
analysis, 1990 through 2004.

We found that using 2 years of data would result in larger average 
fluctuations in matching rates from year to year than states currently 
experience. Our simulation of matching rates from 1990 to 2004 showed 
that when rates were computed using 2 years of PCI data instead of 3, 
the average percentage point change in rates from year to year 
increased to 0.44, from 0.39 under current law. A small number of 
states experienced substantially larger fluctuations (more than 0.5 
percentage points larger) under this strategy than they currently 
experience. The effects of these fluctuations for individual states 
would depend on whether they represented a substantial increase or 
decrease in federal funds. Depending on the scope of a state's Medicaid 
program, a 0.5 percentage point difference in the matching rate would 
have meant a difference of $1.7 million to $77.1 million in federal 
matching funds for a given state in 2003[Footnote 24]. In 8 of 14 
years, fewer than 22 states would have experienced larger fluctuations 
in their matching rates than they experienced under current 
law,[Footnote 25] and in 9 of 14 years, fewer than 4 states would have 
experienced fluctuations that were more than 0.5 percentage points 
larger.[Footnote 26]

States Could Determine Their Own Needs for Assistance with Medicaid- 
Specific Loans or a National Rainy Day Fund:

Giving states the option to decide whether and to what extent they need 
federal assistance could take the form of a loan, either from the 
federal government or from the private capital market (subsidized and 
possibly guaranteed by the federal government), or a Medicaid-specific 
national rainy day fund. We considered the features of existing 
intergovernmental loan programs and state rainy day funds to better 
understand how these programs are structured and utilized by states. 
Implementation of this strategy would require approval of legislation 
to authorize a Medicaid-specific loan program or national rainy day 
fund as well as appropriation of federal funds to cover any federal 
expenditures required for either the loan program or national rainy day 
fund. While this strategy would provide states with greater autonomy 
over their receipt of additional federal assistance, their ability to 
utilize either broad approach would depend on their debt restrictions, 
their borrowing costs, the availability of future state revenues to 
repay loans, and their willingness to participate in a Medicaid- 
specific loan or national rainy day program. State participation also 
could depend on the depth and duration of states' downturns (deep or 
shallow and short or long) and the availability of state funds to fill 
funding gaps. Federal funding required for this strategy could vary 
depending on factors such as whether federal subsidies are included in 
a loan program or whether a national rainy day fund includes federal 
matching funds as well as decisions on the overall federal budget.

Design Considerations:

To identify the factors likely to be involved in designing this 
strategy, we considered the features of existing intergovernmental loan 
programs and state rainy day funds to better understand how these 
programs are structured, how they are utilized by states, and how they 
could contribute to a conceptual model of this strategy [Footnote 27]. 
This strategy draws on the features of existing programs to inform our 
understanding of ways to increase the states' role in determining the 
timing and targeting of increased federal assistance to the states 
during economic downturns. We analyzed approaches to this strategy 
based on two broad methods of providing federal credit: (1) a loan, 
administered directly from the federal government or indirectly through 
the private capital market (subsidized and possibly guaranteed by the 
federal government); and (2) a Medicaid-specific national rainy day 
fund that could distribute federal fiscal assistance during an economic 
downturn. Implementation of one or more approaches to this strategy 
would require numerous decisions about the use, structure, financing, 
and repayment of a loan or national rainy day fund. Any new federal 
loan program would have to comply with the Federal Credit Reform Act of 
1990 requirements that budget authority sufficient to cover the 
program's cost to the government be provided in advance, before new 
direct loan obligations could be incurred or new loan guarantee 
commitments could be made.

Direct Intergovernmental Loans:

Congress could authorize a new federal program so that states could 
borrow funds directly from the federal government based on a rate- 
setting and repayment process specified in law. For example, the law 
could specify that rates be determined by the Treasury based partially 
on Treasury's borrowing costs. CMS could be designated as the 
administering agency. This approach could allow states that might 
otherwise face high interest rates in the private capital market access 
to federal funds that reflect a lower interest rate subsidy. The 
administering agency would have to develop a method to estimate any 
subsidy costs (e.g., the estimated long-term cost to the federal 
government on a net-present value basis of all cash flows to and from 
the government, such as interest rate subsidies and defaults over the 
life of the loan) in order to conform with the Federal Credit Reform 
Act of 1990 [Footnote 28]. The administering agency would have to 
analyze and control the risk and cost of the program, obtain budget 
authority and record outlays to cover the subsidy cost of the program, 
and could also specify loan repayment terms. States would have to 
designate funding sources to repay the loans.

Facilitated Private Lending:

Under this approach, instead of lending money directly to states, the 
federal government could facilitate private lending, such as through a 
guaranteed loan [Footnote 29]. The federal government could help offset 
the risk of lending money to states by covering all or part of the risk 
of loan defaults and by providing an interest subsidy to states. This 
approach would enable the federal government to minimize direct 
involvement with the loan process by placing the burden of loan 
administration on third- party nonfederal lenders. However, the 
administering agency would still have to analyze and control the risk 
and cost of the program and obtain budget authority to cover the 
subsidy costs. States would still have to identify repayment sources. 
State-managed capital access programs, in which state governments 
provide a fixed share of lenders' loan loss reserves, provide another 
model for possible consideration and adaptation to facilitate private 
lending.

National Rainy Day Fund:

Legislative approval of a Medicaid-specific national rainy day fund 
would allow states to pool their resources to help cope with the 
increased costs of Medicaid during economic downturns. We previously 
found that the adequacy of states' own rainy day funds is unknown and 
that choices on competing priorities would have to be made in a fiscal 
crisis [Footnote 30]. Furthermore, some states have placed caps and 
restrictions on the use of these funds [Footnote 31]. States could 
capitalize a national rainy day fund in whole or in part, depending on 
whether the program design included matching contributions from the 
federal government. Determining the amount of money that each state 
should pay into a national rainy day fund would present an additional 
design challenge, given that state Medicaid programs vary widely in the 
population groups and services covered.

Effects:

States' decisions about whether to access any new federal Medicaid 
loans or a national rainy day fund could depend on the nature of the 
economic downturn in terms of when and to what extent states experience 
increased unemployment, each state's own resources, and the design 
features of the program. States generally have resources available to 
weather short-term economic downturns but may be more likely to utilize 
a loan or national rainy day fund approach when they are affected by a 
deeper downturn. States with a 50 percent federal matching rate could 
also view federal loans or a national rainy day fund as an additional 
tool for increasing funding on a short-term basis during an economic 
downturn, filling gaps created by a matching rate that does not 
necessarily rise when additional funds are needed. However, some states 
also face constraints on their ability to borrow because of statutory 
or constitutional debt restrictions and most states have some form of 
balanced budget requirements [Footnote 32]. Consequently, states might 
not be able to take advantage of a loan program.

The effects of either a loan or national rainy day fund approach would 
also depend on the numerous technical decisions required, including, 
but not limited to, interest rates, repayment terms, allowable uses of 
funds, borrowing limits, and any requirements governing maintenance of 
states' efforts in providing their own funds or Medicaid eligibility. A 
direct or guaranteed loan could give states greater autonomy in 
determining their need for assistance but would also result in a 
requirement to repay the loans (an additional financial burden for 
states) as they try to recover from an economic downturn. States would 
have to consider the availability of future revenues to repay loans and 
their borrowing costs, as well as statutory debt restrictions that 
could limit their loan access. A national rainy day fund could allow 
states to pool risk and thereby spend less than they would if they 
chose to establish individual Medicaid rainy day funds or address 
economic downturn-related Medicaid cost increases on an as-needed 
basis. However, representatives of public policy and research 
organizations we contacted cautioned that states may be reluctant to 
contribute to a national fund that could be drawn down by other states 
or tapped by the federal government. The impact on federal outlays of 
this strategy could depend on subsidy costs as well as whether the 
federal government provided matching funds for a national rainy day 
fund. Unless mandated, state participation in a loan or national rainy 
day fund would likely depend on the terms of the program as well as 
state economic circumstances.

Concluding Observations:

Economic downturns, typically accompanied by increases in unemployment, 
can leave states with increased demand for Medicaid program services 
and spending, decreased revenues to help states finance the increased 
demand, and few strategies for grappling with difficult fiscal 
circumstances that will not place them in worse financial positions in 
the future. Current federal and state approaches to help states cope 
with the increased cost of Medicaid during economic downturns present 
temporary solutions to a recurring combination of circumstances. Having 
an automatic mechanism in place to address significant downturns in the 
economy could provide for a more predictable and targeted response to 
states' situations. The targeted supplemental assistance and loan or 
national rainy day fund strategies considered in this report illustrate 
potentially more responsive measures that could help states adjust to 
economic downturns similar to the last three national recessions. 
However, each also presents challenges.

No single strategy or combination of strategies for providing federal 
financial assistance could fully meet the varied economic needs of all 
states at all times. Any strategy also is inhibited by the lags 
inherent in the collection and publication of data, thus limiting its 
ability to have a real-time effect. However, the first and third 
strategies--targeting supplemental assistance to states most affected 
by a downturn and allowing states to determine their own need for 
assistance from a national rainy day fund or loan--could potentially 
better address some of the difficulties faced by states during 
downturns in a more timely and cost-efficient manner than the JGTRRA, 
which provided assistance to all states. Additionally, these two 
strategies are not mutually exclusive and could be used in combination.

Any strategy to help states cope with increased Medicaid costs during 
economic downturns requires trade-offs as Congress seeks to provide 
assistance to states that have the greatest financial need and the 
least capacity to meet those needs while balancing the federal 
government's own long-term fiscal challenges. While none of the 
strategies may fully satisfy all dimensions of targeting, timing, and 
increasing states' own options, Congress may find one or more of these 
strategies useful as starting points in considering whether and how to 
provide supplemental Medicaid assistance during the most difficult 
economic times faced by states.

Agency Comments:

We provided the Secretary of Health and Human Services (HHS) with a 
draft of this report. HHS stated that it did not have comments.

As agreed with your offices, we plan no further distribution of this 
report until 28 days from its date, unless you publicly announce its 
contents earlier. At that time, we will send copies of this report to 
the Secretary of Health and Human Services and the Administrator of the 
Centers for Medicare & Medicaid Services. We will also make copies 
available to others upon request. In addition, the report will be 
available at no charge on the GAO Web site at [hyperlink, 
http://www.gao.gov]. 

If you or your staffs have any questions about this report, please 
contact Kathryn G. Allen at (202) 512-7118 or Stanley J. Czerwinski at 
(202) 512-6806. Contact points for our Offices of Congressional 
Relations and Public Affairs may be found on the last page of this 
report. GAO staff who made major contributions to this report are 
listed in appendix V.

Signed by: 

Kathryn G. Allen: 
Director, Health Care:

Signed by: 

Stanley J. Czerwinski: 
Director, Strategic Issues:

[End of section]

Appendix I: Objectives, Scope, and Methodology: 

This appendix describes our objectives and the scope and methodology of 
the work we did to address them, including how we illustrated the range 
of economic conditions affecting states during economic downturns. We 
include a list of the organizations we contacted during the course of 
our work. 

Objectives and Scope: 

We explored the design considerations and potential effects of 
strategies aimed at helping states with their share of Medicaid 
expenditures during an economic downturn by (1) targeting supplemental 
funds to specific states on the basis of the relative depth and 
duration of their economic downturns as well as the extent to which 
their Medicaid enrollment and expenditures are likely to increase 
during a downturn, (2) using 2 years of per capita income (PCI) data 
instead of the 3 years of data required by statute to compute federal 
matching rates in an attempt to better reflect states’ current economic 
conditions, and (3) providing states with options for obtaining 
assistance from a Medicaid-specific national rainy day fund or loan 
based on their own determination of need. 

Identifying and Evaluating the Strategies: 

To address the objectives, we: 

* analyzed research, including prior GAO reports and other policy 
proposals, that assessed the effects of economic downturns on Medicaid 
enrollment and expenditures across states, the responsiveness of the 
current Medicaid formula to the effects of economic downturns, and 
differences in Medicaid expenditures across states; 

* simulated the potential effects of the strategies to use fewer years 
of data to compute federal matching rates and target supplemental 
federal assistance; and: 

* analyzed the features of existing intergovernmental loan programs and 
state rainy day funds as potential models for providing states with 
discretion in determining the timing and targeting of assistance 
through a federal government-sponsored Medicaid-specific loan program 
or rainy day fund. 

To evaluate the strategies identified, we: 
* conducted statistical simulations of the strategies by comparing the 
actual matching rates in states during recessionary times with the 
matching rates that could exist under the strategies to provide 
targeted supplemental Medicaid assistance and have Medicaid matching 
rates better reflect states’ current economic conditions; 
* consulted with experts in Medicaid financing issues on our targeting 
simulation in terms of its design and suggestions to refine it, and: 
* discussed the strategies with key research groups and state 
associations to discern the potential utility of the strategies as well 
as the feasibility of states’ implementing different strategies. 

Table 4 summarizes the three strategies considered for this report. 
Appendixes II, III, and IV provide additional detail regarding the 
analysis of these strategies.

Table 4: Analysis of Three Strategies to Help States Respond to 
Increased Medicaid Costs during Economic Downturns:  

Goal of strategy: Provide targeted supplemental Medicaid assistance; 
Approach: Target supplemental funds to states based on projected 
Medicaid spending increases and depth and duration of economic 
downturn; 
Analysis: Identify design considerations involved in defining national 
downturns and distributing supplemental federal funds; Estimate amounts 
states would receive based on economic conditions present during three 
prior recessions.

Goal of strategy: Have Medicaid matching rates better reflect states’ 
current economic conditions; 
Approach: Use 2 years of PCI data in the statutory formula used to 
compute federal matching rates; Analysis: Compare matching rates 
computed using 2 years of PCI data to rates based on the 3 years of PCI 
data required under current law; 
Analyze extent to which existing matching rates and matching rates 
based on 2 years of PCI data were consistent with states’ economic 
circumstances. 

Goal of strategy: Provide states with options to improve timing and 
targeting of increased Medicaid assistance; 
Approach: Allow states to determine whether and when they need 
increased assistance in response to economic downturns; 
Analysis: Identify considerations involved in designing loans or a 
national rainy day fund; Identify potential effects based on structure 
and use of existing intergovernmental loan programs.

Source: GAO. 

[End of table]

Illustrating the Range of Economic Conditions Affecting States during 
Economic Downturns: 

To illustrate the potential ability of each strategy to help states 
address increased expenditures during economic downturns, we analyzed 
how implementation of each strategy might differ with respect to the 
varied economic effects of downturns, including (1) early onset of a 
shallow downturn, (2) early onset of a deeper downturn, (3) later onset 
of a shallow downturn, and (4) later onset of a deeper downturn. We 
also reviewed examples of states whose matching rates generally 
remained at the lowest level allowable by federal statute. 

Organizations GAO Contacted: 

We contacted representatives of public policy and research 
organizations to (1) gain insights into various issues, such as the 
extent to which strategies could help states cope with the Medicaid-
related fiscal consequences of economic downturns; (2) obtain referrals 
to related research; (3) validate our selection of strategies; and (4) 
obtain views regarding the feasibility and utility of the three 
strategies, as well as to discuss the potential effects of these 
strategies. The organizations we contacted were as follows: 

American Enterprise Institute: 
Cato Institute: 
Center on Budget and Policy Priorities: Heritage Foundation: 
National Association of State Budget Officers: National Conference of 
State Legislatures: National Governors Association. 

In addition, we consulted with technical experts from Federal Funds 
Information for States and The Urban Institute regarding our 
simulations for the strategies to target supplemental Medicaid 
assistance to specific states based on the depth and duration of their 
economic downturns as well as their Medicaid expenditures and to use 2 
instead of 3 years of PCI data to calculate federal matching rates.

Data and Data Reliability: 

We obtained and analyzed data on personal income and state population 
from the Bureau of Economic Analysis, data on unemployment from the 
Bureau of Labor Statistics, and data on Medicaid expenditures from the 
Centers for Medicare & Medicaid Services. We discussed our use of these 
data with agency officials and reviewed relevant documentation. On the 
basis of these efforts and our use of the data to illustrate potential 
policy strategies and their simulated effects, we determined that the 
data were sufficiently reliable for this report. 

[End of section] 

Appendix II: Designing a Strategy of Targeted Supplemental Medicaid 
Assistance: 

This appendix describes the design decisions and policy considerations 
involved in creating a strategy aimed at targeting supplemental funds 
to states based on the extent to which their Medicaid expenses increase 
during an economic downturn. This supplemental assistance strategy 
would leave the existing Medicaid formula unchanged and add a new, 
separate assistance formula that would operate only during times of 
economic downturn and use variables and a distribution mechanism that 
differ from those used for calculating matching rates. The strategy 
would require policy decisions on three basic steps: (1) deciding when 
to start and stop the supplemental assistance to states, (2) 
determining the level of assistance provided (including defining the 
formula for distributing funds), and (3) deciding how to distribute the 
assistance (principally, deciding whether assistance should be an 
incremental increase in federal matching rates or provided as a lump-
sum grant payment). To illustrate these design considerations, we 
developed a model to simulate supplemental assistance. The following 
sections describe the choices made to simulate and illustrate the 
resulting supplemental assistance as well as some possible 
alternatives. 

Design Considerations for Starting and Stopping Assistance: 

This section presents information about how we chose unemployment as 
the indicator for an economic downturn and how we selected the rules 
for starting and stopping the provision of supplemental assistance. We 
reviewed how these rules would have applied to the past three 
recessions (2001, 1991-1992, and 1981-1983) using our simulation model. 

Choice of Unemployment as an Indicator: 

We used unemployment as the key variable because it reflects the 
potential for increases in Medicaid enrollment as a result of an 
economic downturn. Although other indicators of economic downturn are 
widely reported and important in other contexts,[Footnote 33] experts 
consider increases in unemployment to be an indicator of the likely 
increase in Medicaid enrollments of adults and children.[Footnote 34] 
To simulate how supplemental assistance could be provided, we used 
Bureau of Labor Statistics (BLS) unemployment data by state. Monthly 
BLS unemployment data by state become available with a lag of less than 
one quarter.[Footnote 35]

Use of Unemployment as an Economic Indicator: 

Ideally, the indicator used should reflect the economic downturn and 
exclude other influences such as long-term trends, seasonal influences, 
and other shorter fluctuations. In order to minimize the influence of 
seasonality and the month-to-month fluctuations on the unemployment 
data used in our model simulations, we used a quarterly average of 
seasonally adjusted unemployment data for the 12 most recent 
months.[Footnote 36] Because the level of unemployment is driven by 
trends in the structure of a state’s economy, we used increases in 
unemployment during a period of economic downturn as our measure of the 
effects of the economic cycle.[Footnote 37] (The problem of deciding on 
a base period from which to calculate those increases in unemployment 
was a key issue that is discussed later in this appendix.) This is an 
inexact method for isolating the effects of cyclical downturn on 
unemployment, especially if the trend should change along with the 
economic downturn. For example, if an economic downturn is a 
precipitating event that leads to long-lasting declines in a state’s 
manufacturing industries, at some point the state’s increases in 
unemployment are attributable to structural change in its economy. When 
the increases in unemployment are long term rather than cyclical, this 
may be a policy consideration in deciding when to stop the supplemental 
assistance.

Alternative Indicators of Downturns and Increases in Medicaid 
Enrollments: 

Economists generally prefer indicators other than unemployment to 
signal economic downturns. Unemployment sometimes lags behind the 
cyclical turns in the economy; it can be both slow to increase when the 
downturn begins and slow to return to pre-downturn levels when other 
indicators show the economy is recovering. In general, other indicators 
show an earlier and briefer downturn than unemployment. 

For example, researchers at the Philadelphia Federal Reserve Bank 
developed a monthly index of four state economic indicators intended to 
coincide with the economic cycle.[Footnote 38,39] Such a broad index of 
economic conditions could provide a more reliable and timely indication 
of a state’s cyclical downturn than unemployment. Furthermore, if the 
purpose of supplemental assistance was to include the provision of some 
countercyclical stimulus—that is, provide incentives to increase 
spending to boost macroeconomic activity—rather than to help states 
address the impacts of the downturn on increased Medicaid expenditures, 
then an alternative to unemployment as a variable for triggering 
funding would have better prospects for providing well-timed 
assistance. 

However, there is some leeway in providing supplemental assistance to 
compensate states for the impact of a downturn on their Medicaid 
enrollments and spending. According to experts, states have budget 
resources and financial management techniques to temporarily sustain 
them for a year or two with downturn-driven increases in Medicaid 
expenditures. To assist states with the costs of Medicaid enrollment 
increases, the relatively brief lags caused by using unemployment rates 
to trigger supplemental assistance payments would not present a problem.

Starting and Stopping Supplemental Assistance: 

Supplemental federal assistance could be set to begin payments to 
states when economic evidence shows a significant number of states are 
in an economic downturn. For example, when a certain number of states 
have each exceeded a specified increase in their unemployment rate, 
supplemental assistance could be authorized to begin for the next 
quarter. 

A similar criterion could be used to stop payments. Such a rule could 
be designed to provide a high degree of certainty that the nation had 
entered a downturn and that states were not all in recovery. For our 
simulation model, we chose the rule that payments to states would begin 
when 23 or more had an increase in their unemployment rate of 10 
percent or more from the comparable quarter a year earlier, and 
payments would stop when fewer than 23 states had increases of 10 
percent or more.[Footnote 40] We chose 23 states and a 10 percent or 
more increase in unemployment on the basis of a review of states’ 
unemployment rates over past economic cycles and made a judgment that 
these levels would provide considerable certainty that an economic 
slowdown was nationwide. Other thresholds could be selected to tighten 
or loosen the parameters to start and stop supplemental federal 
assistance. 

Automatic Trigger Design Objectives and Issues: 

An automatic trigger would need to specify several key parameters or 
rules that together would control when assistance payments would begin, 
how long they would last, and when they would stop. Though the trigger 
would control all supplemental assistance payments, it should utilize 
state-by-state data rather than national aggregates because it involves 
assistance to state Medicaid programs. The trigger should distinguish 
between small up-and-down movements in unemployment, which could be 
associated with an economy that is basically stagnant, from those 
movements that clearly show a state whose economy has entered a 
downturn. The trigger must clearly identify the duration of the period 
of economic downturn because of the previously mentioned difficulty of 
separating a state’s trend in unemployment from its cyclical changes. 
Furthermore, the design decision should involve consideration of 
potential risks. A trigger that is too sensitive could provide more 
payments than are reasonably justified by the economic downturn, while 
a trigger with standards that are too rigorous would penalize states 
whose downturns are exceptionally long-lasting, early or late. Also, an 
automatic trigger for supplemental assistance would need to be designed 
with some degree of simplicity and transparency. 

An Illustrative Automatic Trigger: 

For our simulation model, state payments would be triggered when 23 or 
more states had an increase of 10 percent[Footnote 41] or more in the 
state’s unemployment rate compared to the same quarter in the previous 
year, and payments would stop when those conditions were no longer 
present. This trigger consists of three key elements: 
* a threshold number of states (23); 
* a threshold percentage increase in the unemployment rate (10 percent 
or more), and: 
* a “retrospective assessment” used to derive the percentage increase 
in the unemployment rate compared to the same quarter in the previous 
year. 

We chose the two threshold values of 23 states and 10 percent or more 
to work in tandem to ensure that when the program starts, the national 
economy has entered a downturn and that many states (at least 23 and 
probably more) are not yet in recovery.[Footnote 42] We chose both 
numbers based on a review of states’ unemployment rates over past 
economic cycles and made a judgment that these levels would provide 
considerable certainty that the economic slowdown was nationwide. 

To illustrate the application of this trigger, figure 5 shows the 
number of states with a 10 percent or greater increase in their 
unemployment rate from the same quarter a year earlier for the period 
from 1979 through the third quarter of 2004.[Footnote 43] This period 
covers three recessions and offers supplemental assistance as follows: 
* for the 2001 recession, 7 quarters of assistance is provided 
beginning in the first quarter of 2002 and ending as of the fourth 
quarter of 2003; 
* for the 1991-1992 recession, 6 quarters of assistance is provided 
beginning with the fourth quarter of 1991 and ending as of the second 
quarter of 1993; and: 
* for the 1981-1983 recession, 11 quarters of assistance is provided in 
two phases, with the first phase beginning in the fourth quarter of 
1980 and ending as of the second quarter of 1982, and the second phase 
resuming assistance in the fourth quarter of 1982 and ending as of the 
first quarter of 1984. 

Each recessionary period has different characteristics. For example, 
the 1991-1992 recessionary period shows a more gradual increase in 
unemployment compared to the other recessions—and fewer states are 
affected.[Footnote 44]

Figure 5: Number of States with a 10 Percent or More Increase in Their 
Unemployment Rate Compared to the Same Quarter 1 Year Earlier, 1979-
2004:

The is a vertical bar graph. The vertical axis represents number of 
states from 0 to 50. The horizontal axis represents quarters per year 
fro 1979 through 2004. There is a vertical bar for every quarter, and a 
horizontal line indicating the 23-state trigger.

[See PDF for image]

Source: GAO analysis of BLS data.

[End of figure]

Performance of the Automatic Trigger: 

A rough method of evaluating the performance of the automatic trigger 
is the degree to which the period it identifies encompasses states’ 
increases in unemployment in that period.[Footnote 45] The trigger must 
delineate a period of payments that coincides well with most states’ 
increases in the number of unemployed, in order for the supplemental 
federal assistance calculated on the basis of those unemployment 
increases to also be well targeted. Overall, about 90 percent of the 
unemployment increases in the period from the second quarter of 2000 
through the fourth quarter of 2004 are captured by the time period of 
the trigger plus the 1-year retrospective assessment used by the 
simulation model. When the trigger identifies the start of the first 
quarter of the program of supplemental federal assistance, then the 
process of computing each state’s assistance for that first quarter and 
each subsequent quarter of assistance takes place. As part of that 
process, the simulation model calculates each state’s increase in 
unemployment, which is the increase in unemployment compared to the 
base quarter. For each state, the base quarter is whatever quarter had 
the lowest unemployment within the preceding 4 quarters. Thus, though 
the program begins in the first quarter of 2002, it could use states’ 
increases in unemployment that occurred as early as the first quarter 
of 2001. Figure 6 shows the sum of states’ increases in unemployment 
over the previous quarter for the first quarter of 2000 through the 
fourth quarter of 2005. While the trigger in the first quarter of 2002 
appears late relative to when some states actually experienced an 
increase in unemployment, the simulation model’s retrospective 
assessment captures much of the preceding unemployment.

Figure 6: Total of States’ Quarterly Increase in Unemployment Covered 
by Simulation Model’s Supplemental Assistance: 

This is a line graph. The vertical axis represents number of unemployed 
in thousands, from 0 to 600. The horizontal axis represents yearly 
quarters from 2000 through 2005. Also indicated on the graph are the 
payment calculation period (first quarter, 2001 through first quarter 
2002) and the payment period (first quarter 2002 through third quarter 
2003).

[See PDF for image]

Source: GAO analysis of BLS data.

[End of figure]

Use of Alternative Parameters in the Automatic Trigger: 

A lower threshold for the increase in the unemployment rate or 
requiring a smaller number of states to pass that threshold could 
trigger supplemental assistance somewhat sooner and provide more 
quarters of payments (especially for states that may enter a downturn 
much earlier or later than others). These parameters would also have 
potential disadvantages: (1) they could provide less certainty that 
there has been a nationwide downturn, and (2) with more quarters of 
supplemental assistance, the overall cost could be greater (other 
things remaining the same). To show the way in which the threshold 
parameters included in our simulation model work together, figure 7 
displays the effects of choosing alternative combinations of these 
parameters for the period 2000 through 2005. For example, if we use 21 
rather than 23 states, supplemental assistance would be triggered with 
the same first quarter but last for 8 rather than 7 quarters. Many 
adjoining cells of the figure have the same first quarter and number of 
quarters because small changes in the threshold parameters may not 
change when supplemental assistance is triggered. However, over the 
broad ranges shown in the figure, the clear pattern is that lowering 
the percentage increase or lowering the number of states generally 
moves in the direction of an earlier first quarter and a greater number 
of quarters of payments. 

Figure 7: Effects of Alternative Threshold Parameters on the Start and 
Number of Quarters of Supplemental Assistance, 2000 through 2005: 

This chart depicts the quarter and year assistance would begin and the 
number of quarters of assistance provided based on the percentage 
increase in unemployment rate and the number of states. The vertical 
axis of the chart represents the percentage increase in unemployment 
rate from 6 to 16. The horizontal axis represents the number of states 
from 9 to 37. The combination used in GAO's simulation was 23 states 
with a 10 percent increase in unemployment rate: in this simulation 
assistance would begin in the first quarter of 2002, and assistance 
would be provided for seven quarters.

[See PDF for image]

Source: GAO analysis of BLS data.

Note: Number in bold font are those used in GAO's simulation. 

[End of figure] 

The trigger for our simulation is based on the increase in the 
unemployment rate over the same quarter of the previous year. Depending 
on congressional preferences, the period could instead be longer than 1 
year, or it could be based on the increase from the pre-downturn 
levels. Because unemployment is slower to recover than other economic 
indicators, it may be a number of years into the national recovery 
before unemployment rates return to the levels immediately preceding 
the downturn. Therefore, the effect of a longer retrospective 
assessment would be to provide supplemental assistance for more 
quarters and also to provide more assistance to the states with longer-
lasting or late downturns. Using a shorter period reflects a policy 
judgment that the program should be temporary and, in particular, that 
after 1 year the states should then adjust their budgets and programs 
to reflect changed economic conditions.[Footnote 46] 

Alternative Ways to Start and Stop Supplemental Assistance: 

An alternative way to start and stop supplemental assistance is through 
legislation. Congress could consider other indicators and criteria to 
start or stop assistance with the intention of implementing other 
policy objectives. For example, decisions could be made regarding 
limiting the number of quarters of payments or stopping payments after 
spending caps are reached. Additionally, instead of an automatic 
trigger, supplemental assistance could begin when Congress enacted 
legislation. However, enacting appropriately funded and timely 
legislation under the pressure of worsening national and state 
economies presents its own challenges. Studies of the past performance 
of discretionary federal fiscal policy actions in response to recession 
have shown instances of enactment of belated and inappropriate levels 
of fiscal stimulus.[Footnote 47] Also, some of the groups we contacted 
for this study believed that an “automatic trigger” based on economic 
criteria would be the most likely method of implementing assistance in 
a consistent and timely manner.[Footnote 48] 

Determining the Level of Supplemental Assistance: 

There are three important aspects to determining the level of 
supplemental assistance. First, a level of funding must be developed. 
The level of funding in our model is based on the average costs to 
states attributable to increases in unemployment. Second, the estimates 
and allocations of quarterly funding must be consistent with the annual 
appropriations process. Third, assistance needs to be targeted to 
states on the basis of the impact of increases in unemployment on their 
Medicaid programs. 

Level of Funding: 

Several studies in the economics literature have estimated a 
relationship between changes in unemployment rates and changes in 
Medicaid spending while holding constant other factors that influence 
Medicaid spending.[Footnote 49] While these models cannot provide state-
by-state estimates of enrollment increases, they provide national 
average estimates from which we can calculate an average amount of 
additional federal Medicaid spending per additional unemployed person. 
We have chosen to use the estimate of $300 per additional unemployed 
person derived from a recent econometric study of the responsiveness of 
Medicaid enrollments and spending to changes in unemployment rates and 
other factors, such as states’ spending on certain Medicaid 
populations.[Footnote 50] Based on the depth of the 2001 recession, the 
amount of federal assistance would have been $4.2 billion. 

Funding and the Appropriations Process: 

Given the difficulties of forecasting the depth and duration of a 
downturn, as well as the pace of the recovery, estimating the cost of 
supplemental assistance can be difficult. However, within the context 
of the overall Medicaid program, the amount of supplemental assistance 
provided in our simulation ($4.2 billion) is relatively small—less than 
1 percent of total Medicaid spending for a 2-year period. As an open-
ended matching grant that provides states with an incremental increase 
to their matching rates, funding may need to be appropriated.[Footnote 
51] Similarly, supplemental assistance designed to provide a lump-sum 
grant or to be closed-ended, could also require an appropriation 
amount. The funding would need to be apportioned across quarters of the 
fiscal year in order to provide proportionately equal treatment between 
the states that enter a downturn early and those that enter late, 
presuming equal treatment is defined as providing states with equal 
funding for equal increases in unemployment and commensurate with state 
Medicaid populations (all other factors remaining the same). Past 
economic data show that the middle quarters of the supplemental 
assistance are certain to have much greater increases in unemployment 
than the earlier and later quarters (see fig. 5).[Footnote 52] 
Therefore, a policy of spending until funds are gone would seem to 
leave the states with late-starting downturns, or prolonged 
contractions, at risk of receiving little or no supplemental funding. 

Allocation Model: 

Our simulation model targets funds to states in proportion to the 
product of two factors. The first is the state’s increase in the number 
of unemployed persons in that quarter compared to the number of 
unemployed in the base quarter.[Footnote 53] The second factor is a 
Medicaid spending index intended to adjust the first factor for the 
relative size of the states’ Medicaid programs for the nonelderly. The 
first factor is intended to gauge the impact of the economic downturn 
on Medicaid enrollment in the state. The factor is the amount by which 
unemployment for the most recent quarter exceeds the number of 
unemployed in the base quarter. The base quarter is the quarter with 
the lowest number of unemployed in the year immediately preceding the 
first quarter in which assistance is triggered. However, if the state’s 
number of unemployed decreased after the first quarter, that lowest 
quarter would then become the base quarter unemployment. If a state has 
a decrease in the number of unemployed compared to the base quarter, it 
would not receive funding because of a lack of discernible impact from 
the economic downturn. However, states with even small increases in the 
number of unemployed would receive some assistance, in proportion to 
the increase in unemployment.[Footnote 54] We excluded increases in the 
number of unemployed that predated this retrospective assessment. 
Presumably, such increases would be small and possibly unrelated to the 
nationwide economic downturn. 

The purpose of the second factor is to adjust the number of unemployed 
for the relative cost of state Medicaid programs. Two states with an 
equal increase in the number of unemployed could have very different 
increases in Medicaid expenditures, depending on their rate of Medicaid 
spending. The Medicaid index is calculated for each state as its 
average Medicaid spending per nonelderly poor person relative to the 
national average. Thus, a state whose Medicaid spending per nonelderly 
person in poverty was equal to the national average would have an index 
value equal to one (1.00). CMS spending data are used to approximate 
each state’s Medicaid spending for the cyclically sensitive population. 
Census Bureau data provide an estimate of adults and children in 
poverty, who are the potential beneficiaries of such Medicaid spending. 

The Medicaid index factor would not be updated quarterly because it is 
intended to supply relative positions of the states and not quarterly 
impacts of the economic cycle.[Footnote 55] The Medicaid index varies 
widely among the states because of differing Medicaid program 
characteristics and funding efforts. If Congress did not want 
supplemental assistance funding to reflect the full magnitude of 
variations in Medicaid spending, constraints could be designed to 
moderate this factor, or it could be eliminated from the methodology 
for allocating supplemental assistance. 

Deciding How to Distribute Supplemental Assistance: 

Matching Assistance or Lump-sum Grants: 

Assistance could be provided either as an incremental increase to 
states’ federal matching rates or as a lump-sum grant. Representatives 
of one organization we contacted preferred matching assistance on the 
grounds that it would better ensure maintenance of state contributions 
to the Medicaid program, in contrast to lump-sum grant payments that 
could more readily allow states to reduce their own Medicaid spending 
effort and thus use state funds for other purposes. Supplemental 
federal assistance as described in this appendix could be provided as a 
targeted incremental increase in each state’s matching rate or targeted 
lump-sum grant to states. Either approach could provide a state with a 
comparable amount of funding. 

Calculation of Lump-sum and Matching Assistance Amounts: 

Supplemental assistance could provide either a lump-sum grant to each 
state or a comparable level of funding through an incremental increase 
in the state’s matching rate. The lump-sum formula would provide funds 
in proportion to the state’s increase in the number of unemployed, with 
that increase adjusted by the index of relative Medicaid cost. The 
increase in the Medicaid matching rate is calculated by dividing the 
lump-sum grant amount by a state’s total Medicaid spending. Thus, if a 
state left its Medicaid spending unchanged, it would receive the full 
assistance amount. 

Simulation Model Results: 

This section highlights results from our supplemental targeted 
assistance simulation model for the 1998 through 2004 time 
span.[Footnote 56] Individual states vary in different recessions in 
terms of unemployment levels and supplemental federal assistance that 
would result from changes in the number of unemployed. A state with 
minimal unemployment increases in one recession can experience much 
greater increases in the number of unemployed in another recession. The 
widely differing nature of states’ experiences suggests that simulated 
supplemental assistance is unlikely to reflect what a particular state 
would receive in a future economic downturn. 

Table 5 shows data related to the factors used in the formula and the 
resulting supplemental assistance, by state. As shown in table 5, the 
average percentage increase in the number of unemployed ranged from 0.1 
to about 80 percent. With a few exceptions, every state would begin 
receiving assistance during the first quarter of 2002 and would receive 
7 quarters of payments. The next column shows the Medicaid index used, 
and the final two columns show the average increase in each state’s 
matching rate during the 7 quarters, with and without the Medicaid 
expenditure index factor. Because of the importance of the Medicaid 
expenditure index in determining assistance (especially to those states 
with relatively large or small indexes), we present the assistance 
computed with and without the Medicaid factor. In general, the 
simulated increases in matching rates show the targeting with respect 
to the variations in the increases in unemployment that the formula is 
designed to provide. This targeting is especially apparent for the 
supplemental matching rates that exclude the Medicaid index. For some 
states, the Medicaid index is an important determinant of the 
supplemental assistance, but much less important to those states whose 
index value is closer to the U.S. average of 1.00. For example, table 5 
shows that Alaska’s average percentage point increase in matching rate 
would more than triple by including the Medicaid expenditure index, 
increasing from 0.26 to 0.86. In contrast, Oregon’s average percentage 
point increase in matching rate experienced a minimal change by 
including the Medicaid expenditure index, increasing from 1.68 to 1.70.

Table 5: Simulated Supplemental Assistance for Economic Conditions of 
the 2001 Downturn: 

State: Alabama; 
Average percentage increase in unemployment: 22.6; 
Initial payment quarter: 2002Q1; 
Number of quarters: 7; 
Index of Medicaid expenditures per nonelderly person in poverty[a] 
(U.S.=1.000): 0.654; 
Average percentage point increase in matching rate, Excluding Medicaid 
expenditure index: 0.54; 
Average percentage point increase in matching rate, Including Medicaid 
expenditure index: 0.43.

State: Alaska; 
Average percentage increase in unemployment: 9.8; 
Initial payment quarter: 2002Q1; 
Number of quarters: 7
Index of Medicaid expenditures per nonelderly person in poverty[a] 
(U.S.=1.000): 3.272; 
Average percentage point increase in matching rate, Excluding Medicaid 
expenditure index: 0.26; 
Average percentage point increase in matching rate, Including Medicaid 
expenditure index: 0.86.

State: Arizona; 
Average percentage increase in unemployment: 40.9; 
Initial payment quarter: 2002Q1; 
Number of quarters: 7; 
Index of Medicaid expenditures per nonelderly person in poverty[a] 
(U.S.=1.000): 1.078; 
Average percentage point increase in matching rate, Excluding Medicaid 
expenditure index: 1.00; 
Average percentage point increase in matching rate, Including Medicaid 
expenditure index: 1.08.

State: Arkansas; 
Average percentage increase in unemployment: 19.8; Initial payment 
quarter: 2002Q1; 
Number of quarters: 7; 
Index of Medicaid expenditures per nonelderly person in poverty[a] 
(U.S.=1.000): 0.685; 
Average percentage point increase in matching rate, Excluding Medicaid 
expenditure index: 0.49; 
Average percentage point increase in matching rate, Including Medicaid 
expenditure index: 0.33. 

State: California; 
Average percentage increase in unemployment: 27.4; 
Initial payment quarter: 2002Q1; 
Number of quarters: 7; 
Index of Medicaid expenditures per nonelderly person in poverty[a] 
(U.S.=1.000): 0.933; 
Average percentage point increase in matching rate, Excluding Medicaid 
expenditure index: 2.36; 
Average percentage point increase in matching rate, Including Medicaid 
expenditure index: 1.61.

State: Colorado; 
Average percentage increase in unemployment: 80.3; 
Initial payment quarter: 2002Q1; 
Number of quarters: 7; 
Index of Medicaid expenditures per nonelderly person in poverty[a] 
(U.S.=1.000): 0.682; 
Average percentage point increase in matching rate, Excluding Medicaid 
expenditure index: 2.36; 
Average percentage point increase in matching rate, Including Medicaid 
expenditure index: 1.61.

State: Connecticut; 
Average percentage increase in unemployment: 68.9; 
Initial payment quarter: 2002Q1; 
Number of quarters: 7; 
Index of Medicaid expenditures per nonelderly person in poverty[a] 
(U.S.=1.000): 1.576; 
Average percentage point increase in matching rate, Excluding Medicaid 
expenditure index: 1.12; 
Average percentage point increase in matching rate, Including Medicaid 
expenditure index: 1.77.

State: Delaware; 
Average percentage increase in unemployment: 16.8; 
Initial payment quarter: 2002Q1; 
Number of quarters: 7; 
Index of Medicaid expenditures per nonelderly person in poverty[a] 
(U.S.=1.000): 2.429; 
Average percentage point increase in matching rate, Excluding Medicaid 
expenditure index: 0.34; 
Average percentage point increase in matching rate, Including Medicaid 
expenditure index: 0.83. 

State: District of Columbia; 
Average percentage increase in unemployment: 12.7; 
Initial payment quarter: 2002Q1; 
Number of quarters: 7; 
Index of Medicaid expenditures per nonelderly person in poverty[a] 
(U.S.=1.000): 1.553; 
Average percentage point increase in matching rate, Excluding Medicaid 
expenditure index: 0.24; 
Average percentage point increase in matching rate, Including Medicaid 
expenditure index: 0.37. 

State: Florida; 
Average percentage increase in unemployment: 40.2; 
Initial payment quarter: 2002Q1;
Number of quarters: 7; 
Index of Medicaid expenditures per nonelderly person in poverty[a] 
(U.S.=1.000): 0.705; 
Average percentage point increase in matching rate, Excluding Medicaid 
expenditure index: 1.13; 
Average percentage point increase in matching rate, Including Medicaid 
expenditure index: 0.80. 

State: Georgia; 
Average percentage increase in unemployment: 29.2; 
Initial payment quarter: 2002Q1; 
Number of quarters: 7; 
Index of Medicaid expenditures per nonelderly person in poverty[a] 
(U.S.=1.000): 1.059; 
Average percentage point increase in matching rate, Excluding Medicaid 
expenditure index: 0.74; 
Average percentage point increase in matching rate, Including Medicaid 
expenditure index: 0.78. 

State: Hawaii; 
Average percentage increase in unemployment: 8.8; 
Initial payment quarter: 2002Q1; 
Number of quarters: 6; 
Index of Medicaid expenditures per nonelderly person in poverty[a] 
(U.S.=1.000): 2.309; 
Average percentage point increase in matching rate, Excluding Medicaid 
expenditure index: 0.27; 
Average percentage point increase in matching rate, Including Medicaid 
expenditure index: 0.63. 

State: Idaho; 
Average percentage increase in unemployment: 15.1; 
Initial payment quarter: 2002Q1; 
Number of quarters: 7; 
Index of Medicaid expenditures per nonelderly person in poverty[a] 
(U.S.=1.000): 0.852; 
Average percentage point increase in matching rate, Excluding Medicaid 
expenditure index: 0.59; 
Average percentage point increase in matching rate, Including Medicaid 
expenditure index: 0.50. 

State: Illinois; 
Average percentage increase in unemployment: 33.8; 
Initial payment quarter: 2002Q1; 
Number of quarters: 7; 
Index of Medicaid expenditures per nonelderly person in poverty[a] 
(U.S.=1.000): 0.813; 
Average percentage point increase in matching rate, Excluding Medicaid 
expenditure index: 1.16;
Average percentage point increase in matching rate, Including Medicaid 
expenditure index: 0.95. 

State: Indiana; 
Average percentage increase in unemployment: 61.0; 
Initial payment quarter: 2002Q1; 
Number of quarters: 7; 
Index of Medicaid expenditures per nonelderly person in poverty[a] 
(U.S.=1.000): 1.075; 
Average percentage point increase in matching rate, Excluding Medicaid 
expenditure index: 1.37; 
Average percentage point increase in matching rate, Including Medicaid 
expenditure index: 1.48. 

State: Iowa; 
Average percentage increase in unemployment: 36.4; 
Initial payment quarter: 2002Q1; 
Number of quarters: 7; 
Index of Medicaid expenditures per nonelderly person in poverty[a] 
(U.S.=1.000): 1.033; 
Average percentage point increase in matching rate, Excluding Medicaid 
expenditure index: 0.84; 
Average percentage point increase in matching rate, Including Medicaid 
expenditure index: 0.87. 

State: Kansas; 
Average percentage increase in unemployment: 29.3; 
Initial payment quarter: 2002Q1; 
Number of quarters: 7; 
Index of Medicaid expenditures per nonelderly person in poverty[a] 
(U.S.=1.000): 0.665; 
Average percentage point increase in matching rate, Excluding Medicaid 
expenditure index: 1.02; 
Average percentage point increase in matching rate, Including Medicaid 
expenditure index: 0.68. 

State: Kentucky; 
Average percentage increase in unemployment: 30.5; 
Initial payment quarter: 2002Q1; 
Number of quarters: 7; 
Index of Medicaid expenditures per nonelderly person in poverty[a] 
(U.S.=1.000): 0.908; 
Average percentage point increase in matching rate, Excluding Medicaid 
expenditure index: 0.74; 
Average percentage point increase in matching rate, Including Medicaid 
expenditure index: 0.67. 

State: Louisiana; 
Average percentage increase in unemployment: 18.7; 
Initial payment quarter: 2002Q1; 
Number of quarters: 7; 
Index of Medicaid expenditures per nonelderly person in poverty[a] 
(U.S.=1.000): 0.581; 
Average percentage point increase in matching rate, Excluding Medicaid 
expenditure index: 0.44; 
Average percentage point increase in matching rate, Including Medicaid 
expenditure index: 0.26. 

State: Maine; 
Average percentage increase in unemployment: 28.4; 
Initial payment quarter: 2002Q1; 
Number of quarters: 7; 
Index of Medicaid expenditures per nonelderly person in poverty[a] 
(U.S.=1.000): 2.589; 
Average percentage point increase in matching rate, Excluding Medicaid 
expenditure index: 0.49; 
Average percentage point increase in matching rate, Including Medicaid 
expenditure index: 1.28. 

State: Maryland; 
Average percentage increase in unemployment: 24.0; 
Initial payment quarter: 2002Q1; 
Number of quarters: 7; 
Index of Medicaid expenditures per nonelderly person in poverty[a] 
(U.S.=1.000): 1.467; 
Average percentage point increase in matching rate, Excluding Medicaid 
expenditure index: 0.62; 
Average percentage point increase in matching rate, Including Medicaid 
expenditure index: 0.91. 

State: Massachusetts; 
Average percentage increase in unemployment: 67.2; 
Initial payment quarter: 2002Q1; 
Number of quarters: 7; 
Index of Medicaid expenditures per nonelderly person in poverty[a] 
(U.S.=1.000): 1.225; 
Average percentage point increase in matching rate, Excluding Medicaid 
expenditure index: 0.85; 
Average percentage point increase in matching rate, Including Medicaid 
expenditure index: 1.05. 

State: Michigan; 
Average percentage increase in unemployment: 57.9; 
Initial payment quarter: 2002Q1; 
Number of quarters: 7; 
Index of Medicaid expenditures per nonelderly person in poverty[a] 
(U.S.=1.000): 0.712; 
Average percentage point increase in matching rate, Excluding Medicaid 
expenditure index: 1.57; 
Average percentage point increase in matching rate, Including Medicaid 
expenditure index: 1.11. 

State: Minnesota; 
Average percentage increase in unemployment: 46.5; 
Initial payment quarter: 2002Q1;
Number of quarters: 7; 
Index of Medicaid expenditures per nonelderly person in poverty[a] 
(U.S.=1.000): 1.948; 
Average percentage point increase in matching rate, Excluding Medicaid 
expenditure index: 0.84; 
Average percentage point increase in matching rate, Including Medicaid 
expenditure index: 1.63. 

State: Mississippi; 
Average percentage increase in unemployment: 17.1; 
Initial payment quarter: 2002Q1; 
Number of quarters: 7; 
Index of Medicaid expenditures per nonelderly person in poverty[a] 
(U.S.=1.000): 0.821; 
Average percentage point increase in matching rate, Excluding Medicaid 
expenditure index: 0.43; 
Average percentage point increase in matching rate, Including Medicaid 
expenditure index: 0.35. 

State: Missouri; 
Average percentage increase in unemployment: 62.4; 
Initial payment quarter: 2002Q1; 
Number of quarters: 7; 
Index of Medicaid expenditures per nonelderly person in poverty[a] 
(U.S.=1.000): 1.192; 
Average percentage point increase in matching rate, Excluding Medicaid 
expenditure index: 1.11; 
Average percentage point increase in matching rate, Including Medicaid 
expenditure index: 1.32. 

State: Montana; 
Average percentage increase in unemployment: 0.1; 
Initial payment quarter: 2002Q4; 
Number of quarters: 4; 
Index of Medicaid expenditures per nonelderly person in poverty[a] 
(U.S.=1.000): 0.675; Average percentage point increase in matching 
rate, Excluding Medicaid expenditure index: 0.00[B]; Average percentage 
point increase in matching rate, Including Medicaid expenditure index: 
0.00[B]. 

State: Nebraska; 
Average percentage increase in unemployment: 26.0; Initial payment 
quarter: 2002Q1; 
Number of quarters: 7; 
Index of Medicaid expenditures per nonelderly person in poverty[a] 
(U.S.=1.000): 0.973; 
Average percentage point increase in matching rate, Excluding Medicaid 
expenditure index: 0.57; 
Average percentage point increase in matching rate, Including Medicaid 
expenditure index: 0.56. 

State: Nevada; 
Average percentage increase in unemployment: 33.5; 
Initial payment quarter: 2002Q1; 
Number of quarters: 7; 
Index of Medicaid expenditures per nonelderly person in poverty[a] 
(U.S.=1.000): 0.703; 
Average percentage point increase in matching rate, Excluding Medicaid 
expenditure index: 1.78; 
Average percentage point increase in matching rate, Including Medicaid 
expenditure index: 1.25. 

State: New Hampshire; 
Average percentage increase in unemployment: 51.5; 
Initial payment quarter: 2002Q1; 
Number of quarters: 7; 
Index of Medicaid expenditures per nonelderly person in poverty[a] 
(U.S.=1.000): 1.539; 
Average percentage point increase in matching rate, Excluding Medicaid 
expenditure index: 1.01; 
Average percentage point increase in matching rate, Including Medicaid 
expenditure index: 1.55. 

State: New Jersey; 
Average percentage increase in unemployment: 40.8; 
Initial payment quarter: 2002Q1; 
Number of quarters: 7; 
Index of Medicaid expenditures per nonelderly person in poverty[a] 
(U.S.=1.000): 0.735; 
Average percentage point increase in matching rate, Excluding Medicaid 
expenditure index: 0.96; 
Average percentage point increase in matching rate, Including Medicaid 
expenditure index: 0.71. 

State: New Mexico; 
Average percentage increase in unemployment: 8.9; 
Initial payment quarter: 2002Q1; 
Number of quarters: 7; 
Index of Medicaid expenditures per nonelderly person in poverty[a] 
(U.S.=1.000): 1.286; 
Average percentage point increase in matching rate, Excluding Medicaid 
expenditure index: 0.20; 
Average percentage point increase in matching rate, Including Medicaid 
expenditure index: 0.26. 

State: New York; 
Average percentage increase in unemployment: 28.7; 
Initial payment quarter: 2002Q1; 
Number of quarters: 7; 
Index of Medicaid expenditures per nonelderly person in poverty[a] 
(U.S.=1.000): 1.796; 
Average percentage point increase in matching rate, Excluding Medicaid 
expenditure index: 0.34; 
Average percentage point increase in matching rate, Including Medicaid 
expenditure index: 0.61. 

State: North Carolina; 
Average percentage increase in unemployment: 77.4; 
Initial payment quarter: 2002Q1; 
Number of quarters: 7; 
Index of Medicaid expenditures per nonelderly person in poverty[a] 
(U.S.=1.000): 0.915; 
Average percentage point increase in matching rate, Excluding Medicaid 
expenditure index: 1.70; 
Average percentage point increase in matching rate, Including Medicaid 
expenditure index: 1.55. 

State: North Dakota; 
Average percentage increase in unemployment: 16.3; 
Initial payment quarter: 2002Q2; 
Number of quarters: 6; 
Index of Medicaid expenditures per nonelderly person in poverty[a] 
(U.S.=1.000): 0.595; 
Average percentage point increase in matching rate, Excluding Medicaid 
expenditure index: 0.39; 
Average percentage point increase in matching rate, Including Medicaid 
expenditure index: 0.23. 

State: Ohio; 
Average percentage increase in unemployment: 28.5; 
Initial payment quarter: 2002Q1; 
Number of quarters: 7; 
Index of Medicaid expenditures per nonelderly person in poverty[a] 
(U.S.=1.000): 1.041; 
Average percentage point increase in matching rate, Excluding Medicaid 
expenditure index: 0.69; 
Average percentage point increase in matching rate, Including Medicaid 
expenditure index: 0.72. 

State: Oklahoma; 
Average percentage increase in unemployment: 39.7; 
Initial payment quarter: 2002Q1; 
Number of quarters: 7; 
Index of Medicaid expenditures per nonelderly person in poverty[a] 
(U.S.=1.000): 0.667; 
Average percentage point increase in matching rate, Excluding Medicaid 
expenditure index: 0.98; 
Average percentage point increase in matching rate, Including Medicaid 
expenditure index: 0.66. 

State: Oregon; 
Average percentage increase in unemployment: 39.1; 
Initial payment quarter: 2002Q1; 
Number of quarters: 7; 
Index of Medicaid expenditures per nonelderly person in poverty[a] 
(U.S.=1.000): 1.011; 
Average percentage point increase in matching rate, Excluding Medicaid 
expenditure index: 1.68; 
Average percentage point increase in matching rate, Including Medicaid 
expenditure index: 1.70. 

State: Pennsylvania; 
Average percentage increase in unemployment: 26.3; 
Initial payment quarter: 2002Q1; 
Number of quarters: 7; 
Index of Medicaid expenditures per nonelderly person in poverty[a] 
(U.S.=1.000): 1.035; 
Average percentage point increase in matching rate, Excluding Medicaid 
expenditure index: 0.57; 
Average percentage point increase in matching rate, Including Medicaid 
expenditure index: 0.59. 

State: Rhode Island; 
Average percentage increase in unemployment: 18.1; 
Initial payment quarter: 2002Q1; 
Number of quarters: 7; 
Index of Medicaid expenditures per nonelderly person in poverty[a] 
(U.S.=1.000): 1.106; 
Average percentage point increase in matching rate, Excluding Medicaid 
expenditure index: 0.30; 
Average percentage point increase in matching rate, Including Medicaid 
expenditure index: 0.33. 

State: South Carolina; 
Average percentage increase in unemployment: 53.1; 
Initial payment quarter: 2002Q1; 
Number of quarters: 7; 
Index of Medicaid expenditures per nonelderly person in poverty[a] 
(U.S.=1.000): 0.972; 
Average percentage point increase in matching rate, Excluding Medicaid 
expenditure index: 1.17; 
Average percentage point increase in matching rate, Including Medicaid 
expenditure index: 1.14. 

State: South Dakota; 
Average percentage increase in unemployment: 24.9; 
Initial payment quarter: 2002Q1; 
Number of quarters: 7; 
Index of Medicaid expenditures per nonelderly person in poverty[a] 
(U.S.=1.000): 1.122; 
Average percentage point increase in matching rate, Excluding Medicaid 
expenditure index: 0.57; 
Average percentage point increase in matching rate, Including Medicaid 
expenditure index: 0.64. 

State: Tennessee; 
Average percentage increase in unemployment: 27.0; 
Initial payment quarter: 2002Q1; 
Number of quarters: 7; 
Index of Medicaid expenditures per nonelderly person in poverty[a] 
(U.S.=1.000): 1.431; 
Average percentage point increase in matching rate, Excluding Medicaid 
expenditure index: 0.53; 
Average percentage point increase in matching rate, Including Medicaid 
expenditure index: 0.75. 

State: Texas; 
Average percentage increase in unemployment: 34.4; 
Initial payment quarter: 2002Q1; 
Number of quarters: 7; 
Index of Medicaid expenditures per nonelderly person in poverty[a] 
(U.S.=1.000): 0.749; 
Average percentage point increase in matching rate, Excluding Medicaid 
expenditure index: 1.16; 
Average percentage point increase in matching rate, Including Medicaid 
expenditure index: 0.87. 

State: Utah; 
Average percentage increase in unemployment: 61.0; 
Initial payment quarter: 2002Q1; 
Number of quarters: 7; 
Index of Medicaid expenditures per nonelderly person in poverty[a] 
(U.S.=1.000): 00.752; 
Average percentage point increase in matching rate, Excluding Medicaid 
expenditure index: 2.20; 
Average percentage point increase in matching rate, Including Medicaid 
expenditure index: 1.65. 

State: Vermont; 
Average percentage increase in unemployment: 41.0; 
Initial payment quarter: 2002Q1; 
Number of quarters: 7; 
Index of Medicaid expenditures per nonelderly person in poverty[a] 
(U.S.=1.000): 1.992; 
Average percentage point increase in matching rate, Excluding Medicaid 
expenditure index: 0.55; 
Average percentage point increase in matching rate, Including Medicaid 
expenditure index: 1.10. 

State: Virginia; 
Average percentage increase in unemployment: 69.3; 
Initial payment quarter: 2002Q1; 
Number of quarters: 7; 
Index of Medicaid expenditures per nonelderly person in poverty[a] 
(U.S.=1.000): 0.610; 
Average percentage point increase in matching rate, Excluding Medicaid 
expenditure index: 1.77; 
Average percentage point increase in matching rate, Including Medicaid 
expenditure index: 1.08. 

State: Washington; 
Average percentage increase in unemployment: 41.6; 
Initial payment quarter: 2002Q1; 
Number of quarters: 7; 
Index of Medicaid expenditures per nonelderly person in poverty[a] 
(U.S.=1.000): 0.971; 
Average percentage point increase in matching rate, Excluding Medicaid 
expenditure index: 1.41; 
Average percentage point increase in matching rate, Including Medicaid 
expenditure index: 1.37. 

State: West Virginia; 
Average percentage increase in unemployment: 6.3; 
Initial payment quarter: 2002Q3; 
Number of quarters: 5; 
Index of Medicaid expenditures per nonelderly person in poverty[a] 
(U.S.=1.000): 1.345; 
Average percentage point increase in matching rate, Excluding Medicaid 
expenditure index: 0.16; 
Average percentage point increase in matching rate, Including Medicaid 
expenditure index: 0.22. 

State: Wisconsin; 
Average percentage increase in unemployment: 52.3; 
Initial payment quarter: 2002Q1; 
Number of quarters: 7; 
Index of Medicaid expenditures per nonelderly person in poverty[a] 
(U.S.=1.000): 0.422; 
Average percentage point increase in matching rate, Excluding Medicaid 
expenditure index: 1.38; 
Average percentage point increase in matching rate, Including Medicaid 
expenditure index: 0.58. 

State: Wyoming; 
Average percentage increase in unemployment: 8.1; 
Initial payment quarter: 2002Q1; 
Number of quarters: 7; 
Index of Medicaid expenditures per nonelderly person in poverty[a] 
(U.S.=1.000): 1.267; 
Average percentage point increase in matching rate, Excluding Medicaid 
expenditure index: 0.27; 
Average percentage point increase in matching rate, Including Medicaid 
expenditure index: 0.34. 

Source: GAO calculations based on BLS, CMS, and Census data. 

[a] Expenditures for categories that would be cyclically sensitive such 
as spending for children and nondisabled, nonelderly adults. 

[b] Less than 0.005. 

[End of table]

Next are figures showing changes in states’ matching rates resulting 
from the supplemental assistance and changes in unemployment for 
selected states with widely varying economic downturns in order to 
illustrate patterns of simulated supplemental assistance in relation to 
changes in unemployment. These states provide a broader picture to 
illustrate the different economic circumstances that states can 
experience during the same economic downturn. On each of the next four 
figures, the trend line shows the percentage increase in unemployment 
from the base quarter and is plotted with respect to the percentage 
change in unemployment. The bars show supplemental matching rate 
increases, and relate to the increased matching rate. Figure 8 depicts 
a downturn in a state that had increasing unemployment from the first 
quarter of 2000 and shows an increase in unemployment that continues 
through the third quarter of 2004. The bars show that the supplemental 
assistance would be responsive to the increase in unemployment during 
the 7 quarters the state received the assistance.

Figure 8: Simulated Supplemental Assistance for a State with an Early, 
Long, and Deep Economic Downturn: 

This is a combination line and bar graph. The left vertical axis 
represents percentage change in unemployment from -20 to 100. The right 
vertical axis represents increase in matching rate from -0.80 to 4.00. 
The horizontal axis represents quarters from third quarter, 1998 
through fourth quarter, 2004. The line in the graph depicts change in 
unemployment from base quarter (second quarter, 2001). Seven bars 
depict supplemental assistance from first quarter, 2002 through third 
quarter, 2003. Also shown are boxes depicting the payment calculation 
period (first quarter, 2001 through first quarter, 2002) and the 
payment period (first quarter, 2002 through third quarter, 2003).

[See PDF for image]

Source: GAO analysis of BLS, CMS, and Census data.

[End of figure]

In figure 9, the state experiences a “double dip” with increasing, then 
decreasing, and again increasing unemployment. The first increase in 
unemployment is 3 years before the start of simulated supplemental 
assistance in the first quarter of 2002. The second increase begins in 
the second quarter of 2002, so the state misses the first quarter of 
assistance entirely, and the assistance received in the second quarter 
of 2002 would be relatively small. The first increase in unemployment 
is relatively small, so it could be considered a transitory economic 
event rather than a real economic contraction. By the final quarter in 
which supplemental assistance would be provided, unemployment has 
leveled off.

Figure 9: Simulated Supplemental Assistance for a State with a 
Relatively Early, Long-Lasting, and Shallow Downturn: 

This is a combination line and bar graph. The left vertical axis 
represents percentage change in unemployment from -20 to 100. The right 
vertical axis represents increase in matching rate from -0.80 to 4.00. 
The horizontal axis represents quarters from third quarter, 1998 
through fourth quarter, 2004. The line in the graph depicts change in 
unemployment from base quarter (first quarter, 2001). Seven bars depict 
supplemental assistance from first quarter, 2002 through third quarter, 
2003. Also shown are boxes depicting the payment calculation period 
(first quarter, 2001 through first quarter, 2002) and the payment 
period (first quarter, 2002 through third quarter, 2003).

[See PDF for image]

Source: GAO analysis of BLS, CMS, and Census data.

[End of figure]

Figure 10 shows a state with a particularly late and short economic 
downturn, in which unemployment was leveling off by the final quarter 
of the supplemental assistance provided and declining thereafter. 
Nevertheless, the state would have received 5 quarters of supplemental 
assistance. 

Figure 10: Simulated Supplemental Assistance for a State with a Late, 
Short, and Shallow Downturn: 

This is a combination line and bar graph. The left vertical axis 
represents percentage change in unemployment from -20 to 100. The right 
vertical axis represents increase in matching rate from -0.80 to 4.00. 
The horizontal axis represents quarters from third quarter, 1998 
through fourth quarter, 2004. The line in the graph depicts change in 
unemployment from base quarter (second quarter, 2001). Five bars depict 
supplemental assistance from third quarter, 2002 through third quarter, 
2003. Also shown are boxes depicting the payment calculation period 
(first quarter, 2001 through first quarter, 2002) and the payment 
period (first quarter, 2002 through third quarter, 2003).

[See PDF for image]

Source: GAO analysis of BLS, CMS, and Census data.

[End of figure]

Figure 11 shows a state with a short and relatively deep recession. 
Supplemental assistance would have been provided through 7 quarters of 
increased unemployment and would have been phased out about the time 
when unemployment peaked. 

Figure 11: Simulated Supplemental Assistance for a State with a Short, 
Deep Downturn: 

This is a combination line and bar graph. The left vertical axis 
represents percentage change in unemployment from -20 to 100. The right 
vertical axis represents increase in matching rate from -0.80 to 4.00. 
The horizontal axis represents quarters from third quarter, 1998 
through fourth quarter, 2004. The line in the graph depicts change in 
unemployment from base quarter (third quarter, 2001). Seven bars depict 
supplemental assistance from first quarter, 2002 through third quarter, 
2003. Also shown are boxes depicting the payment calculation period 
(first quarter, 2001 through first quarter, 2002) and the payment 
period (first quarter, 2002 through third quarter, 2003).

[See PDF for image]

Source: GAO analysis of BLS, CMS, and Census data.

[End of figure]

[End of section]

Appendix III: Designing a Strategy to Better Reflect States’ Current 
Economic Conditions: 

This appendix presents additional detail about the development and 
analysis of our strategy to use fewer years of per capita income (PCI) 
data to compute Medicaid matching rates. As currently constructed, the 
PCI data in the Medicaid formula reflect economic conditions that 
existed several years earlier.[Footnote 57] The age of the data used to 
calculate the matching rate can result in states not receiving a 
matching rate consistent with their current economic situation because 
state PCI for a particular year becomes available nearly 2 years after 
the start of the calendar year for which the data are reported. 
[Footnote 58] For example, the United States entered a recession in 
2001, but matching rates for 2001 were based on PCI data from 1996 to 
1998, when the national economy was expanding. Efforts to use fewer 
years of data to calculate the matching rate assume that eliminating 
the oldest year of data would more accurately reflect a state’s current 
economic circumstances. We tested this assumption by analyzing the 
effects of using fewer years of data to calculate states’ federal 
matching rates. To develop and analyze this strategy, we reviewed a 
similar proposal published in a 2004 AARP Public Policy Institute 
report [Footnote 59] and our previous work on the Medicaid matching 
formula. [Footnote 60]

Overview of Analysis: 

To analyze the effect of using fewer years of data to calculate the 
matching rates, we used three matching rates that employed the current 
statutory formula but varied in the years of data used (see table 6). 
The first matching rate (“the 3-year matching rate”) mirrors the 
current statutory construction of the Medicaid matching rate 
calculation, using 3 years of PCI data that are 3 to 5 years old. The 
second matching rate (“the 2-year matching rate”) is based on the 
statutory construction, except that it eliminates the oldest year of 
data and uses 2 years of PCI data. The third matching rate (“the 
simulated matching rate”) only uses PCI data for the current year (the 
year in which the calculations are made) and for 1 year prior, thus 
showing no time lag in the data used. Although not feasible to 
implement because of lags in data publication, we devised the simulated 
matching rate in order to evaluate whether changing the years of data 
used to calculate the matching rate resulted in a better approximation 
of states’ current economic circumstances.

Table 6: Matching Rates Used to Analyze Strategy: 

Matching rate: 3-year; 
Description: Uses 3 years of PCI data, as outlined in federal statute; 
Years of PCI data used to calculate matching rate for 2001: 1996-1998. 

Matching rate: 2-year; 
Description: Removes the oldest year of PCI data from the current 
statutory matching rate calculation; 
Years of PCI data used to calculate matching rate for 2001: 1997-1998. 

Matching rate: Simulated; 
Description: Uses current year and 1 prior year of PCI data to 
calculate matching rate; 
Years of PCI data used to calculate matching rate for 2001: 2000-2001. 

Source: GAO analysis using Bureau of Economic Analysis (BEA) PCI data. 

We calculated these matching rates for the period from 1990 through 
2004, which covers the last two national recessions.Footnote 61] We 
then compared (1) the annual percentage point changes in the three 
matching rates with annual percentage changes in PCI and annual 
percentage point changes in the unemployment rate, (2) the simulated 
matching rate with changes in PCI, and (3) the 3-year and 2-year 
matching rates with the simulated matching rate. Finally, we analyzed 
the extent to which the 3-year and 2-year matching rates fluctuated 
from year to year.

Comparison of Changes in Matching Rates with Changes in PCI and 
Unemployment: 

To measure the extent to which the 3-year and 2-year matching rates can 
assist states throughout the economic cycle, we did a correlation 
analysis that compared the annual changes in matching rates with the 
changes in PCI [Footnote 62] and the unemployment rate, two commonly 
used indicators of economic performance. A negative correlation 
coefficient would mean that when current PCI decreased, matching rates 
would increase, and vice versa. A positive correlation coefficient 
would mean that when the current unemployment rate increased, matching 
rates would increase, and vice versa. For example, it would indicate 
that the matching rates would increase assistance provided to the 
states during an economic downturn.

Specifically, we examined the correlation between the annual changes in 
the 3-year matching rate and the percentage change in PCI and the 
annual changes in the 2-year matching rate and the percentage change in 
PCI. For the 3-year and 2-year matching rates, to offer states relief 
during an economic downturn, the correlation should be negative. In 
other words, a decline in PCI would be associated with an increased 
matching rate. (Similarly, in an economic upturn the matching rates 
would decline.) However, we found that the correlation between the 
changes in the 3-year and 2-year matching rates, and the changes in PCI 
fluctuated (see fig. 12). Changes in current economic conditions were 
essentially uncorrelated with changes in matching rates during this 
time period. [Footnote 63] For example, while a moderate positive 
correlation existed in 1990 (+0.54 and +0.47 for the respective 3-year 
and 2-year matching rates), the correlation became negative for both 
the 3-year and 2-year matching rates 4 years later. For most years, 
correlations between 3-year and 2-year matching rates followed similar 
patterns, but occasionally they diverged. For example, in 1993, the 3-
year matching rate had a negative correlation (-0.25), while the 2-year 
matching rate essentially showed no correlation (0.04). Importantly, 
during the recession years 1990 through 1991 and 2001, the correlation 
coefficients were positive. Therefore, this indicated a declining 
current PCI associated with a declining matching rate. Consequently, 
the 3-year and 2-year matching rates do not tend to assist the states 
during economic downturns.

Figure 12: Correlations of the Changes in the 3-Year and 2-Year 
Matching Rates with Changes in PCI: 

This is a bar graph with the vertical axis representing Correlation 
coefficient from -0.30 to 0.60. The horizontal axis represents years, 
from 1990 through 2004. For each year, there are two bars: one depicts 
the 3-year matching rate correlation with PCI; the other depicts the 2-
year matching rate correlation with PCI.

[See PDF for image] 

Source: GAO. 

[End of figure]

We also examined the relationship between the changes in the 3-year and 
2-year matching rates and changes in the unemployment rate. If the 
matching rates assisted the states during periods of increased 
unemployment, the relationship between the change in matching rates and 
the change in the unemployment rate would be positive. In other words, 
increases in the unemployment rate would be associated with increases 
in the matching rates, and vice versa. Similar to the results with PCI, 
the relationship is mixed—in some years, the relationship is positive 
and in some it is negative (see fig. 13). In the 1990-1991 recession, 
the relationship was negative, indicating that increases in the 
unemployment rate were associated with decreased matching rates. In the 
2001 recession, the relationship was positive: increases in 
unemployment were associated with increased matching rates. 

Figure 13: Correlations of the Changes in the 3-Year and 2-Year 
Matching Rates with Changes in the Unemployment Rates: 

This is a bar graph with the vertical axis representing Correlation 
coefficient from -0.50 to 0.50. The horizontal axis represents years, 
from 1990 through 2004. For each year, there are two bars: one depicts 
the 3-year matching rate correlation with PCI; the other depicts the 2-
year matching rate correlation with PCI.

[See PDF for image] 

Source: GAO. 

Note: A positive correlation coefficient would show that when 
unemployment increased, matching rates would also increase. 

[End of figure]

Comparison of Changes in PCI with Changes in the Simulated Matching 
Rate: 

To assess whether the simulated matching rate provided a better 
approximation of states’ current economic conditions as measured by 
changes in PCI, we did a correlation analysis of the changes in PCI 
with the changes in the simulated matching rate, which is based on the 
current and prior year’s PCI. Comparing changes in PCI with the 
simulated matching rates allowed us to assess whether (1) the time lag 
in the data affected the correlation between matching rates and changes 
in PCI or (2) the construction of the matching rate formula itself 
affected the correlation between matching rates and changes in PCI. The 
correlation between the changes in PCI and the changes in the simulated 
matching rate is uniformly negative during the period from 1990 through 
2004 (see fig. 14), suggesting that the matching formula structure is 
not the cause of the mixed relationship. 

Figure 14: Correlations of the Changes in the Simulated Matching Rate 
with the Changes in PCI, 1990 to 2004: 

This is a bar graph with the vertical axis representing Correlation 
coefficient from -0.80 to 0.00. The horizontal axis represents years, 
from 1990 through 2004. For each year a bar depicts the negative change 
in the simulated match rate. 

[See PDF for image] 

Source: GAO. 

[End of figure]

Overall, the changes in the simulated matching rate provided a more 
consistent link to changes in states’ PCI than did the changes in the 2-
year and 3-year matching rates. Decreases in PCI were consistently 
associated with increases in the simulated matching rates. Conversely, 
increases in PCI were associated with decreases in the matching rates. 
The correlation coefficients ranged from -0.79 to -0.31, thus 
indicating variations in the strength of the relationship during the 
time period. The relationship between matching rates and PCI reflects 
that the simulated matching rate is constrained by the 50 percent floor 
in some states, whereas changes in PCI do not reflect this constraint. 
[Footnote 64] This reduces the correlation. For example, although 
Connecticut’s PCI fluctuated more than the majority of the states, its 
matching rate remained at the 50 percent floor during the entire 1990 
to 2004 time period. The number of states affected by the 50 percent 
floor during this time period varied from 10 to 12. In addition, the 
simulated matching rate used a 2-year average of PCI, whereas the 
changes in PCI reflected year-to-year differences in PCI. The matching 
rate formula also squares PCI, thus reducing the correlation between 
PCI and the simulated matching rate. (PCI changes are linear. The 
squared PCI values in the simulated matching rate resulted in nonlinear 
changes.) 

The 2-year PCI average in the simulated matching rate reduced the 
annual PCI fluctuations. As a result, the annual correlations between 
the simulated matching rate and PCI fluctuated depending on the 
underlying volatility of PCI across states.

Comparisons of Changes in the 3-Year and 2-Year Matching Rates with 
Changes in the Simulated Matching Rate: 

We also compared changes in the 3-year and 2-year matching rates with 
changes in the simulated matching rate to determine whether a 2-year 
matching rate better approximated states’ current economic conditions. 
Figure 15 shows the annual correlation coefficients of the 3-year and 2-
year matching rates compared with the simulated matching rate. A higher 
positive correlation coefficient for the 2-year matching rate would 
indicate that the 2-year matching rate is more sensitive to changes in 
current economic conditions than the 3-year matching rate. The 
generally negative correlation indicates that the 3-year and 2-year 
matching rates do not track the current economic conditions reflected 
in the simulated matching rate. In general, the correlations of the 3-
year and 2-year matching rates with the simulated matching rate were 
practically identical during the entire period, 1990 to 2004 (on 
average, -0.130 and -0.135, respectively). These correlations 
fluctuated during the period of analysis and ranged from -0.58 (1991) 
to 0.28 (1993). The correlations were negative during the 1990-1991 
recession, indicating that the matching rates would not have assisted 
states during this economic downturn. However, in the 2001 recession, 
the correlations were essentially zero. 

Figure 15: Correlations of the Changes in 3-Year and 2-Year Matching 
Rates with the Changes in the Simulated Matching Rate: 

This is a bar graph with the vertical axis representing Correlation 
coefficient from -0.70 to 0.40. The horizontal axis represents years, 
from 1990 through 2004. For each year, there are two bars: one depicts 
the 3-year matching rate correlation with PCI; the other depicts the 2-
year matching rate correlation with PCI.

[See PDF for image] 

Source: GAO. 

Note: A positive correlation coefficient would mean that when PCI 
increased, matching rates would decrease. 

[End of figure]

The lack of substantial positive correlations during either recession 
is of particular concern because it indicates that when the states are 
under the most economic stress, the matching rates for states decline 
or, at best, remain on average unchanged. These correlation results 
occur because when PCI declines, the 3-year and 2-year matching rates 
depend upon PCI data that reflect economic conditions of several years 
earlier. 

Comparisons of 2-Year and 3-Year Matching Rates in Year-to-Year 
Fluctuations: 

We analyzed the extent to which the 2-year and 3-year matching rates 
differed in year-to-year percentage point changes by comparing annual 
differences in matching rates to understand whether a reduction in the 
number of years of PCI data in the matching rate formula (from 3 years 
to 2 years of PCI data) yielded changes that differed from the year-to-
year percentage point changes resulting from the current, statutory 
matching rate. We compared year-to-year percentage point changes in 
matching rates for the 2-year matching rate and the 3-year matching 
rate. As expected, the 3-year PCI average produced a smoother time 
trend than a 2-year average. In general, the 2-year matching rates 
showed slightly larger year-to-year fluctuations compared with the 3-
year matching rates. 

Specifically, from 1990 through 2004, we found that: 
* 43 percent of the annual changes in 2-year matching rates exceeded 
the changes in the 3-year matching rates; 
* 33 percent of the annual changes in the 3-year matching rates 
exceeded the changes in the 2-year matching rates; and: 
* 24 percent of the annual changes were identical (reflecting those 
states at the 50 percent matching rate floor). (See table 7.)

Table 7: Comparison of States’ Year-to-Year Differences in 2-Year and 3-
Year Matching Rates, 1990-2004: 

Differences in the changes in the matching rates (percentage points): 1 
or more; 
Number of instances 2-year matching rate exceeded 3-year matching rate: 
7; 
Percentage of instances 2-year matching rate exceeded 3-year matching 
rate: 1.0; 
Number of instances 3-year matching rate exceeded 2-year matching rate: 
0; 
Percentage of instances 3-year matching rate exceeded 2-year matching 
rate: 0.0. 

Differences in the changes in the matching rates (percentage points): 
0.5 to less than 1; 
Number of instances 2-year matching rate exceeded 3-year matching rate: 
31; 
Percentage of instances 2-year matching rate exceeded 3-year matching 
rate: 4.3; 
Number of instances 3-year matching rate exceeded 2-year matching rate: 
22; 
Percentage of instances 3-year matching rate exceeded 2-year matching 
rate: 3.1. 

Differences in the changes in the matching rates (percentage points): 
0.25 to less than 0.5; 
Number of instances 2-year matching rate exceeded 3-year matching rate: 
87; 
Percentage of instances 2-year matching rate exceeded 3-year matching 
rate: 12.2; 
Number of instances 3-year matching rate exceeded 2-year matching rate: 
51; 
Percentage of instances 3-year matching rate exceeded 2-year matching 
rate: 7.1. 

Differences in the changes in the matching rates (percentage points): 
Greater than 0 to less than 0.25; 
Number of instances 2-year matching rate exceeded 3-year matching rate: 
182; 
Percentage of instances 2-year matching rate exceeded 3-year matching 
rate: 25.5; 
Number of instances 3-year matching rate exceeded 2-year matching rate: 
165; 
Percentage of instances 3-year matching rate exceeded 2-year matching 
rate: 23.1.  

Source: GAO analysis of changes for current 3-year matching rate and 
proposed 2-year matching rate. 

Notes: Differences represent differences in the absolute-value annual 
changes in 3-year matching rates with absolute-value annual changes in 
2-year matching rates.  

The second and fourth columns represent the number of instances any 
state experienced a variation within this range during 1990 to 2004.  

The third and fifth columns represent the percentage of states 
experiencing a variation within this range between 1990 and 2004.  

There were 169 instances with no state differences between the 2-year 
and 3-year matching rate changes. This lack of variation reflects 
states whose matching rates were at the 50 percent matching rate floor 
and thus had no annual changes. 

[End of table] 

In those years in which the 2-year matching rate exceeded the 3-year 
matching rate, it occasionally did so by a wide margin. For example, 
the 2-year matching rates in a few states—in several years—had an 
annual change 1 percentage point greater than the annual change in the 
3-year matching rate. [Footnote 65] The changes in the 3-year matching 
rates never exceeded the changes in the 2-year matching rates by more 
than 1 percentage point.  

[End of section] 

Appendix IV: Information on Selected Intergovernmental Loan Programs 
and State Rainy Day Funds:  

This appendix contains information about some of the existing programs 
we reviewed to understand the design decisions and policy 
considerations involved in a strategy to allow states to determine 
whether and when to access increased federal Medicaid assistance in 
response to economic downturns. These programs provided a conceptual 
framework for reviewing existing design alternatives that could inform 
consideration of a potential Medicaid-specific loan or national rainy 
day fund. We examined features of existing federal programs that 
include intergovernmental loan components. [Footnote 66] In addition, 
we examined state rainy day funds as well as prior GAO work to inform 
our understanding of some of the issues likely to be involved in 
creating a Medicaid-specific national rainy day fund. [Footnote 67] 

Selected Intergovernmental Loan Programs:  

The Environmental Protection Agency’s (EPA) Clean Water State Revolving 
Fund (CWSRF) program provides an independent, permanent, low-cost 
source of financing for a wide range of efforts to protect or improve 
water quality. [Footnote 68] Through the CWSRF, EPA provides annual 
grants to the states to capitalize state-level CWSRFs. States must 
match these EPA grants with a minimum of 20 percent of their own 
contributions. States loan their CWSRF dollars to local governments and 
other entities for various water quality projects, and loan repayments 
are cycled back into the state-level programs to fund additional 
projects. In June 2006, we reported that, since 1987, the 50 states as 
well as Puerto Rico have used 96 percent (about $50 billion) of their 
CWSRF dollars to build, upgrade, or enlarge conventional wastewater 
treatment facilities and conveyances. Although the CWSRF is primarily a 
low-interest loan program, states can also use it to refinance, 
purchase, or guarantee local debt and purchase bond insurance. States 
may customize their loan terms, including interest rates (from 0 
percent to market rates) and repayment periods (up to 20 years), 
depending on the financial and environmental needs of potential 
borrowers. All programs are also subject to annual independent 
financial audits.  

The Federal Emergency Management Agency (FEMA) provides Community 
Disaster Loans (CDL) to local governments in designated disaster areas 
that have suffered a substantial loss of tax and other revenue. The 
state’s governor requests a presidential declaration of an emergency or 
disaster through the FEMA Regional Director. Once the president has 
made the declaration, loans can be provided up to a maximum of $5 
million. Loans are not to exceed 25 percent of the local government’s 
annual operating budget for the fiscal year in which the major disaster 
occurs. The CDL program provides for loan forgiveness (cancellation) 
when it is determined that the affected government will not be able to 
repay the loan for 3 fiscal years following a disaster. A total of 55 
CDLs were made from the initiation of the program in August 1976 
through September 30, 2005. Of the 55 loans made, 36 were paid back in 
part or in full. [Footnote 69]  

The Temporary Assistance for Needy Families (TANF) program offers block 
grants under which states receive federal funds to design and operate 
their own welfare programs within federal guidelines. TANF also offers 
a direct loan program to provide assistance to states. This program is 
funded though a permanent appropriation of $1.7 billion. States can 
access direct loan funds for any purpose for which TANF grants can be 
used, such as welfare assistance, but states must repay any loans 
within 3 years. However, in 2001, we reported that the TANF loan 
program is likely the wrong mechanism to provide assistance during a 
fiscal crisis because states are eligible for better financing terms in 
the tax-exempt municipal bond market and because officials in some 
states had indicated that borrowing specifically for social welfare 
programs in times of fiscal stress would not incur popular support. 
[Footnote 70] No state had applied for a TANF loan prior to 2005. In 
2005, Congress made a TANF loan available to three states affected by 
Hurricane Katrina—Alabama, Louisiana, and Mississippi—and included 
language stating that penalties would not be imposed against these 
states for failure to repay the loan or interest on the loan.  

Unemployment Insurance (UI), administered by the U.S. Department of 
Labor in partnership with the states, provides temporary cash benefits 
to eligible workers who become involuntarily unemployed. Eligibility 
for UI benefits, benefit amounts, and the length of time benefits are 
available are determined by state law, within broad federal guidelines. 
The UI system is funded through federal and state taxes levied on 
employers. States deposit their taxes with the U.S. Treasury, which 
maintains one trust fund with a separate account for each state. States 
are responsible for ensuring the solvency of their individual trust 
funds, which they use to pay benefits to UI claimants in their states. 
To ensure solvency, states may choose to build trust fund reserves 
during good economic times so that if unemployment rises they will have 
reserves sufficient for paying UI claims without raising taxes or 
borrowing money from the federal government. If states have 
insufficient reserves for paying claims, they may request a loan from 
the federal government. [Footnote 71] The federal government maintains 
a loan trust fund, which is built up using a portion of the federal UI 
tax. The Federal Unemployment Account (FUA) funds loans to state 
unemployment compensation programs. If states fail to repay any loans 
within the time frame specified in statute, [Footnote 72] the federal 
taxes on employers in a state increase each year the debt is not paid. 
As of July 2006, the FUA had a balance of about $13 billion, and one 
state had an outstanding loan totaling about $238 million. [Footnote 
73] States utilize the loan program periodically.  

State Rainy Day Funds:  

According to the National Association of State Budget Officers (NASBO), 
almost all states have established rainy day funds as one way to cope 
with fiscal constraints that states experience. These fiscal 
constraints can be imposed either by law, such as balanced budget 
requirements and borrowing restrictions, or by bond markets, which 
encourage states to provide funding in advance for particular budgetary 
uncertainties. [Footnote 74] Without adequate reserves available to 
mitigate a fiscal crisis, states without short-term borrowing 
capabilities would have little choice but to reduce spending, increase 
revenue, or make other short-term budget adjustments. Even if a state 
is permitted to borrow short-term to fund unanticipated needs, the 
practice may be viewed unfavorably by bond-rating agencies that 
establish credit ratings for states and therefore play a role in 
determining a state’s borrowing costs.  

State rainy day fund requirements vary in a number of ways. [Footnote 
75] Some state rainy day funds can be used only in years of economic 
downturn (determined through formulas) or in the case of a revenue 
shortfall or a deficit. State rainy day funds also may include 
requirements specifying whether funds can be used for general purposes, 
agency-specific purposes, or in the event of natural disasters or other 
emergencies. States may also require a minimum rainy day fund balance. 
The National Conference of State Legislatures (NCSL) recommends a 
minimum rainy day fund balance of 5 percent. 

[End of section] 

Appendix V: GAO Contacts and Staff Acknowledgments:  

GAO Contacts:  

Kathryn G. Allen, (202) 512-7118: 
Stanley J. Czerwinski, (202) 512-6806 

Acknowledgments: Major contributors included Assistant Directors 
Michael Springer and Carolyn L. Yocom; and Meghana Acharya, Robert 
Dinkelmeyer, Greg Dybalski, Nancy Fasciano, Jerry Fastrup, Summer 
Lingard, Romonda McKinney, Donna Miller, Elizabeth T. Morrison, and 
Michelle Sager.  

[End of section]  

Footnotes: 

[1] In fiscal year 2004, total expenditures for the Medicaid program 
(federal and state) were about $298 billion. 

[2] The $10 billion temporary increase in federal Medicaid funding made 
available through JGTRRA provided supplemental Medicaid funding to 
states for the last two calendar quarters (April through September) of 
fiscal year 2003 and the first three calendar quarters (October through 
June) of fiscal year 2004.  

[3] The federal matching rate is intended to adjust for differences in 
state fiscal capacity and reduce program benefit disparities across 
states by providing more federal funds to states with weaker tax bases. 
For fiscal year 2006, federal matching rates ranged from 50 to 76 
percent of state Medicaid expenditures. 

[4] See GAO, Federal Assistance: Temporary State Fiscal Relief, GAO-04-
736R (Washington, D.C.: May 7, 2004); GAO, Medicaid Formula: 
Differences in Funding Ability among States Often Are Widened, GAO-03-
620 (Washington, D.C.: July 10, 2003); Miller and Schneider, The 
Medicaid Matching Formula: Policy Considerations and Options for 
Modification, #2004-09, AARP Public Policy Institute (Washington, D.C.: 
September 2004); and GAO, Medicaid: Restructuring Approaches Leave Many 
Questions, GAO/HEHS-95-103 (Washington, D.C.: Apr. 4, 1995).  

[5] GAO-04-736R.  

[6] Throughout this report, the term state refers to the 50 states and 
the District of Columbia.  

[7] We analyzed the past three recessions—1981 through 1983, 1991 
through 1992, and 2001—to understand differences in the timing, depth, 
and duration of different economic downturns. However, similar economic 
patterns may not repeat themselves in future economic downturns.  

[8] Where we conducted simulations for the first and second strategies, 
we asked experts in Medicaid financing issues to provide suggestions 
regarding their construction. 

[9] Stan Dorn, Barbara Markham Smith, and Bowen Garrett, Medicaid 
Responsiveness, Health Coverage, and Economic Resilience: A Preliminary 
Analysis, Prepared for the Health Policy Institute of the Joint Center 
for Political and Economic Studies (Washington, D.C.: Joint Center for 
Political and Economic Studies, Sept. 27, 2005).  

[10] In contrast, 70 percent of Medicaid spending goes to elderly 
individuals and individuals with disabilities, who are least affected 
by economic downturns, as reported by Dorn et al.  

[11] In some cases, expenditures could not be attributed to specific 
beneficiary populations and thus were excluded from these calculations. 

[12] The National Bureau of Economic Research (NBER) identifies 
recessions on the basis of several indicators, including employment, 
sales in the manufacturing and trade sectors, and industrial 
production. A recession is a significant decline in economic activity 
spread across the economy, lasting more than a few months, normally 
visible in real gross domestic product (GDP), real income, employment, 
industrial production, and wholesale-retail sales. A recession begins 
just after the economy reaches a peak of activity and ends as the 
economy reaches its trough. Not all economic downturns are recessions. 
Economic downturns would include—but not be limited to—recessions 
identified by NBER. 

[13] By statute, the federal share of Medicaid spending ranges from 50 
to 83 percent. The 50 percent minimum federal share (“50 percent 
floor”) reflects a federal commitment to fund at least half the cost of 
each state’s Medicaid program. For 2006, 12 states received federal 
matching rates of 50 percent. 

[14] See GAO-03-620.  

[15] OMB Circular A-129 outlines guidelines on federal government 
loans. 

[16] We chose both numbers based on a review of states’ unemployment 
rates over the past three recessions and determined that these levels 
would have provided considerable certainty that the economic slowdown 
was nationwide. 

[17] See Dorn et al. (Sept. 27, 2005).  

[18] For our model, we used Dorn et al.’s estimates to derive an 
average increase in Medicaid expenditures per additional unemployed 
person of $300, which could be adjusted over time by inflation and 
changes in demographics of the Medicaid population. See Dorn et al. 
(Sept. 27, 2005). 

[19] This is an increase of 10 percent or more compared to the 
unemployment rate that existed a year earlier and not a 10 percentage 
point change in unemployment rates. Unless otherwise specified, all 
percentage changes are stated in terms of a percentage increase over a 
base quarter.  

[20] One state received a matching rate increase that was less than 
0.005 percentage points. 

[21] Appendix II provides details on the calculation of this index and 
how it affects the amount of assistance a state would receive. We use 
poverty in lieu of actual enrollments because states vary in terms of 
the services provided and eligibility for those services.  

[22] Changes in states’ federal matching rates can have a significant 
effect on the amount of federal funds available to a state. For 
example, a 0.25 percent increase in states’ federal matching rates for 
2004 would have resulted in a minimum increase in federal funds of more 
than $0.9 million in Wyoming and more than $102 million in New York. 

[23] Although not feasible to implement because of lags in data 
publication, we devised this simulated matching rate in order to 
evaluate whether changing the years of data used to calculate the 
matching rate resulted in a better approximation of states’ current 
economic circumstances. 

[24] These amounts represented 0.08 to 0.29 percent of state own-source 
revenues. Also referred to as general revenues from own sources, these 
revenues are state and local total receipts, excluding federal grants-
in-aid. We excluded from this analysis the 14 states whose matching 
rates in 2003 were at the 50 percent floor or had been established in 
legislation. (As we have previously reported, because of the 50 percent 
floor, some states receive higher federal matching rates than they 
would if their rates were based only on their PCI.)  

[25] Across all of the years of our analysis (1990-2004), the number of 
states that would have experienced larger fluctuations under this 
strategy than under current law ranged from 17 to 27.  

[26] Across all years, the number of states that would have experienced 
fluctuations more than 0.5 percentage points larger under this strategy 
than under current law ranged from 0 to 8. 

[27] Appendix IV includes background information on selected federal 
programs that include intergovernmental loan components. 

[28] The Federal Credit Reform Act of 1990, P.L. 101-508, requires that 
credit subsidy costs be financed from new budget authority and be 
recorded as budget outlays at the time direct or guaranteed loans are 
disbursed. Agencies must have appropriations for the subsidy cost 
before they can enter into direct loan obligations or loan guarantee 
commitments. Subsidy costs include the estimated long-term cost to the 
federal government on a net-present value basis of all cash flows to 
and from the government, such as interest rate subsidies and defaults 
over the life of the loan.  

[29] Specific examples of facilitated lending include The Federal 
Family Education Loan Program and the Health Center Loan Guarantees. 

[30] GAO, Welfare Reform: Challenges in Saving for a “Rainy Day”, GAO-
01-674T (Washington, D.C.: Apr. 26, 2001).  

[31] GAO, Budgeting for Emergencies: State Practices and Federal 
Implications, GAO/AIMD-99-250 (Washington, D.C.: Sept. 30, 1999). 

[32] GAO/AIMD-99-250. 

[33] For example, in its retrospective determination of the dates of 
nationwide economic peaks and troughs, the Business Cycle Dating 
Committee of the National Bureau of Economic Research (a private, 
nonprofit, nonpartisan research organization) relies primarily on real 
gross domestic product (GDP), real income, employment, industrial 
production, and wholesale-retail sales. The Committee views real GDP as 
the single best available measure. These data are not all available at 
the state level. 

[34] Centers for Medicare & Medicaid Services (CMS) data on Medicaid 
enrollments would not be useful for this purpose because they reflect 
both changes in enrollments due to changes in state policies affecting 
eligibility as well as increases in enrollment that are attributable to 
economic downturn.  

[35] More specifically, we used monthly, seasonally adjusted 
unemployment data and unemployment rates from BLS Local Area 
Unemployment Statistics by state.  

[36] Month-to-month fluctuations are dampened by using a quarterly 
rolling average of the 12 most recent months, though it also somewhat 
dampens the indicator’s sensitivity to turns in the economy. However, 
we retained some degree of sensitivity by recomputing these 12-month 
averages for each quarter. For this strategy, when referring to 
unemployment or the unemployment rate, we are referring to the average 
of the 12 most recent months.  

[37] More sophisticated statistical methods could perhaps better 
isolate cyclical change from trends and other noncyclical factors 
causing changes. We chose this quarterly moving average method because 
it offers greater simplicity that helps make the assistance formula 
mechanism easier to explain and understand. 

[38] Theodore M. Crone, “What a New Set of Indexes Tells Us About State 
and National Business Cycles,” Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia 
Business Review (2006, Q1): pp. 11-24.  

[39] The National Bureau of Economic Research establishes widely used 
dates of the start and end of expansions and contractions of the U.S. 
business cycle. These dates are determined retrospectively and would 
not be available on a timely basis for use in an automatic trigger. 

[40] This 10 percent threshold is used as a criterion for beginning 
federal supplemental assistance to states. As explained later in this 
appendix, it does not restrict an individual state’s eligibility. In 
other words, a state with a 2 percent increase in unemployment would 
receive assistance, but its supplemental increase to its matching rate 
would be smaller. 

[41] This is an increase of 10 percent compared to the unemployment 
rate for the same quarter in the previous year and not a 10 percentage 
point change in unemployment rates. Unless otherwise specified, all 
percentage changes in unemployment or unemployment rates for this 
strategy are expressed in terms of a percentage increase over a base 
quarter, and not percentage points. (However, supplemental increases to 
states’ matching rates are reported in percentage points because that 
is the common way to present that information.)  

[42] This is the percentage increase in a state’s unemployment rate 
compared to the same quarter in the previous year (the retrospective 
assessment). We do not use the national unemployment rate as a 
reference point because many states usually remain well above or below 
the national unemployment rate. The use of state-by-state unemployment 
rates is also appropriate because supplemental assistance is intended 
for individual states, whose Medicaid programs vary. 

[43] Note that in all the data displays in this appendix, a 2-quarter 
administrative lag is assumed between the date of the increase in 
unemployment data and the date the supplemental assistance could be 
provided. Such an administrative lag would reflect time for data to 
become available, for allocations to be computed, and for other 
administrative purposes. For example, on a table or figure showing 
unemployment for the third quarter of 2002, those are actually 
unemployment data as of the first quarter of 2002, with the difference 
due to the assumed 2-quarter administrative lag.  

[44] If the onset of the downturn is very gradual, it is more likely 
that fewer states will have the requisite 10 percent increase over the 
unemployment rate from the prior year. 

[45] Note that this is an increase in the number of persons unemployed 
and not the unemployment rate. 

[46] The choices are not merely limited to the choice between a longer 
and shorter retrospective assessment. For example, the retrospective 
assessment could be a weighted average of long and short periods, with 
less weight on the long periods.  

[47] For example, see John Taylor, “Reassessing Discretionary Fiscal 
Policy,” Journal of Economic Perspectives, v. 14, n. 3 (Summer 2000): 
pp. 21-36.  

[48] Congressional action could override any approach in place. For 
example, if there were signs of an incipient national economic 
downturn, supplemental assistance could be enacted ahead of an 
automatic trigger. Alternatively, supplemental assistance could be 
blocked if funding of other budget priorities was deemed more 
important. 

[49] John Holahan and Bowen Garrett, “Rising Unemployment and 
Medicaid,” Urban Institute Health Policy Online (Oct. 16, 2001). This 
description somewhat oversimplifies the econometric methods of these 
studies. For instance, these studies rely on several estimating 
equations, and they also estimate increases in Medicaid enrollments 
from which the impact on Medicaid spending is calculated.  

[50] Stan Dorn, Barbara Markham Smith, and Bowen Garrett, Medicaid 
Responsiveness, Health Coverage, and Economic Resilience: A Preliminary 
Analysis, prepared for the Health Policy Institute of The Joint Center 
for Political and Economic Studies (Washington, D.C.: The Joint Center 
for Political and Economic Studies, Sept. 27, 2005).  

[51] Open-ended matching grants increase the capacity of state and 
local governments to provide services, but because of difficulty in 
predicting expenditures, they create a degree of fiscal uncertainty at 
the federal level. 

[52] This variation by quarter is one reason why calculating quarterly 
supplemental assistance payments could better target funds than 
calculating payments on an annual basis.  

[53] We used the number of unemployed persons rather than the 
unemployment rate because state size must be taken into account. Two 
states with identical unemployment rate increases may have different 
increases in their numbers of unemployed persons. The state with a 
larger increase in the number of unemployed persons would have greater 
resulting Medicaid spending, assuming everything else remained the 
same. This increase in the number of unemployed could be adjusted to 
take into account the change in the labor force from the base period. 
However, we chose not to take this approach to avoid complicating the 
simulation model. 

[54] While states could cope with the impact of small increases in the 
number of unemployed, it could be problematic to specify a level of 
increase that is small enough for states to cope without federal aid. 
Furthermore, because of our inability to separate trends from the 
effects of economic cycles, a fast-growing state that has a small 
increase in the number of unemployed could claim to be significantly 
affected by the national downturn, considering how large its decrease 
in the number of unemployed might have been without the downturn.  

[55] CMS does not make these data available frequently enough to permit 
their use on a quarterly basis by states. For our simulation model, we 
used 2003 expenditure data, which were the most recent data available 
at the time we did our work. 

[56] Similar targeting was displayed in other recessionary periods. 
That is, the targeted assistance was proportional to the increases in 
unemployment. In addition, a relatively small number of states (usually 
different states in each period) would receive small payments because 
their recessions began either earlier or later compared with the 
national downturn. 

[57] For example, the fiscal year 2006 matching rate includes a 3-year 
average of PCI data from 2001 to 2003.  

[58] The age of the data used to calculate the matching rate results 
from both a data reporting lag and an announcement lag. The reporting 
lag occurs because the Bureau of Economic Analysis reports state PCI 
amounts about 9 to 12 months after the end of a calendar year. For 
instance, state PCI for 2004 was reported toward the end of 2005. The 
announcement lag occurs because matching rates are announced 1 year 
before the year in which they become effective. This is referred to as 
the announcement period, because it gives states time to plan their 
budgets based on Medicaid matching rates for the upcoming fiscal year.  

[59] Vic Miller and Andy Schneider, The Medicaid Matching Formula: 
Policy Considerations and Options for Modification, #2004-09, AARP 
Public Policy Institute (Washington, D.C.: September 2004).  

[60] GAO, Medicaid Formula: Differences in Funding Ability among States 
Often Are Widened, GAO-03-620 (Washington, D.C.: July 10, 2003). 

[61] The first recession occurred in 1990-1991. The second recession 
occurred in 2001.  

[62] State PCIs were deflated using the price index for personal 
consumption expenditures from BEA. 

[63] However, in fig. 12, positive correlations were more prevalent 
than negative correlations. 

[64] By statute, the federal share of Medicaid spending ranges from 50 
to 83 percent. The 50 percent minimum federal share (“50 percent 
floor”) reflects a federal commitment to fund at least half the cost of 
each state’s Medicaid program. For 2006, 12 states received federal 
matching rates of 50 percent. 

[65] The standard deviations for the annual changes in the 3-year and 2-
year matching rates, respectively, were 0.52 and 0.60 percent. 

[66] Other loan programs included in our background research were the 
Student Loan Program, the Drinking Water Revolving Loan Program, and 
state Capital Access Programs. Any new federal loan program would have 
to comply with the Federal Credit Reform Act of 1990 requirements that 
agencies have budget authority to cover the program’s cost to the 
government in advance, before new direct loan obligations are incurred 
and new loan guarantee commitments are made.  

[67] GAO, Medicaid: Restructuring Approaches Leave Many Questions, 
GAO/HEHS-95-103 (Washington, D.C.: Apr. 4, 1995).  

[68] GAO, Clean Water: How States Allocate Revolving Loan Funds and 
Measure Their Benefits, GAO-06-579 (Washington, D.C.: June 5, 2006). 

[69] The Community Disaster Loan Act of 2005 (CDLA), provided for up to 
$750 million of disaster funds to be used to subsidize “special” 
community disaster loans, up to a total of $1 billion, for local 
governments to provide essential services. For purposes of these 
special loans, the new law removed the $5 million per loan limit but 
prohibited their cancellation. As of May 3, 2006, 59 special CDL 
applications had been approved for local governments in Louisiana and 
47 for those in Mississippi, for a total of 106 loans.  

[70] GAO, Welfare Reform: Challenges in Saving for a “Rainy Day,” GAO-
01-674T (Washington, D.C.: Apr. 26, 2001). 

[71] They may also choose to increase taxes on employers or raise funds 
through other means such as municipal bonds, which potentially offer a 
lower interest rate.  

[72] If a state has an outstanding balance on January 1 for 2 
consecutive years, it has until November 10 of the second year to repay 
the loan.  

[73] These data were the most recent available balances as of Aug. 
2006.  

[74] GAO, Budgeting for Emergencies: State Practices and Federal 
Implications, GAO/AIMD-99-250 (Washington, D.C.: Sept. 30, 1999).  

[75] NASBO, Budget Processes in the States (Washington, D.C.: January 
2002). 

[End of sction]  

GAO's Mission: 

The Government Accountability Office, the investigative arm of 
Congress, exists to support Congress in meeting its constitutional 
responsibilities and to help improve the performance and accountability 
of the federal government for the American people. GAO examines the use 
of public funds; evaluates federal programs and policies; and provides 
analyses, recommendations, and other assistance to help Congress make 
informed oversight, policy, and funding decisions. GAO's commitment to 
good government is reflected in its core values of accountability, 
integrity, and reliability. 

Obtaining Copies of GAO Reports and Testimony: 

The fastest and easiest way to obtain copies of GAO documents at no 
cost is through GAO’s Web site [hyperlink, http://www.gao.gov]. Each 
weekday, GAO posts newly released reports, testimony, and 
correspondence on its Web site. To have GAO e-mail you a list of newly 
posted products every afternoon, go to [hyperlink, http://www.gao.gov] 
and select “Subscribe to Updates.”  

Order by Mail or Phone:  

The first copy of each printed report is free. Additional copies are $2 
each. A check or money order should be made out to the Superintendent 
of Documents. GAO also accepts VISA and Mastercard. Orders for 100 or 
more copies mailed to a single address are discounted 25 percent. 
Orders should be sent to:  

U.S. Government Accountability Office: 441 G Street NW, Room LM: 
Washington, D.C. 20548:  

To order by Phone: 
Voice: (202) 512-6000: 
TDD: (202) 512-2537: 
Fax: (202) 512-6061:  

To Report Fraud, Waste, and Abuse in Federal Programs:  

Contact:  

Web site: [hyperlink, http://www.gao.gov/fraudnet/fraudnet.htm]: 
E-mail: fraudnet@gao.gov: 
Automated answering system: (800) 424-5454 or (202) 512-7470:  

Congressional Relations:  

Gloria Jarmon, Managing Director, JarmonG@gao.gov: 
(202) 512-4400: 
U.S. Government Accountability Office: 
441 G Street NW, Room 7125: 
Washington, D.C. 20548:  

Public Affairs:  

Paul Anderson, Managing Director, AndersonP1@gao.gov: 
(202) 512-4800: 
U.S. Government Accountability Office: 
441 G Street NW, Room 7149: 
Washington, D.C. 20548: