This is the accessible text file for GAO report number GAO-05-810T 
entitled 'Social Security Reform: Preliminary Lessons from Other 
Countries' Experiences' which was released on June 16, 2005. 

This text file was formatted by the U.S. Government Accountability 
Office (GAO) to be accessible to users with visual impairments, as part 
of a longer term project to improve GAO products' accessibility. Every 
attempt has been made to maintain the structural and data integrity of 
the original printed product. Accessibility features, such as text 
descriptions of tables, consecutively numbered footnotes placed at the 
end of the file, and the text of agency comment letters, are provided 
but may not exactly duplicate the presentation or format of the printed 
version. The portable document format (PDF) file is an exact electronic 
replica of the printed version. We welcome your feedback. Please E-mail 
your comments regarding the contents or accessibility features of this 
document to Webmaster@gao.gov. 

This is a work of the U.S. government and is not subject to copyright 
protection in the United States. It may be reproduced and distributed 
in its entirety without further permission from GAO. Because this work 
may contain copyrighted images or other material, permission from the 
copyright holder may be necessary if you wish to reproduce this 
material separately. 

Testimony Before the Subcommittee on Social Security, Committee on Ways 
and Means, House of Representatives: 

United States Government Accountability Office: 

GAO: 

For Release on Delivery Expected at 10:00 a.m. EDT: 

Thursday, June 16, 2005: 

Social Security Reform: 

Preliminary Lessons from Other Countries' Experiences: 

Statement of Barbara D. Bovbjerg, Director, Education, Workforce, and 
Income Security: 

GAO-05-810T: 

GAO Highlights: 

Highlights of GAO-05-810T, a report to Subcommittee on Social Security,
Committee on Ways and Means, House of Representatives: 

Why GAO Did This Study: 

Many countries, including the United States, are grappling with 
demographic change and its effect on their national pension systems. 
The number of workers for each retiree is falling in most developed 
countries, straining the finances of national pension programs, 
particularly where contributions from current workers fund payments to 
current beneficiaries—known as a “pay-as-you-go” (PAYG) system. 
Although demographic and economic challenges are less severe in the 
U.S. than in many other developed countries, projections show that the 
Social Security program faces a long-term financing problem. Because 
some countries have already undertaken national pension reform efforts 
to address demographic changes similar to those occurring in the U.S., 
we may draw lessons from their experiences. 

The Chairman of the Subcommittee on Social Security of the House 
Committee on Ways and Means asked GAO to testify on preliminary results 
of ongoing work on lessons learned from other countries’ experiences 
reforming national pension systems. GAO focuses on (1) adjustments to 
existing PAYG national pension programs, (2) the creation or reform of 
national pension reserve funds to partially pre-fund PAYG pension 
programs, and (3) reforms involving the creation of individual 
accounts. 

What GAO Found: 

Based on preliminary work, all countries in the Organisation for 
Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD), as well as Chile, have, 
to some extent, reformed their national pension systems, consistent 
with their different economic and political conditions. While reforms 
in one country may not be easily replicated in another, their 
experiences may nonetheless offer lessons for the U.S. Countries’ 
experiences adjusting PAYG national pension programs highlight the 
importance of considering how modifications will affect the program’s 
financial sustainability, its distribution of benefits, the incentives 
it creates, and public understanding of the new provisions. Nearly all 
of the countries we are studying reduced benefits, and most have also 
increased contributions, often by increasing statutory retirement ages. 
Countries included provisions to ensure adequate benefits for lower-
income groups, though these can lessen incentives to work and save for 
retirement. Also, how well new provisions are implemented, 
administered, and explained to the public may affect the outcome of the 
reform. 

Countries with national pension reserve funds designed to partially pre-
fund PAYG pension programs provide lessons about the importance of 
early action and sound governance. Funds that have been in place for a 
long time provide significant reserves to strengthen the finances of 
national pension programs. Countries that insulate national reserve 
funds from being directed to meet other social and political objectives 
are better equipped to fulfill future pension commitments. In addition, 
regular disclosure of fund performance supports sound management and 
administration, and contributes to public education and oversight. 

Countries that have adopted individual account programs—which may also 
help pre-fund future retirement income—offer lessons about financing 
the existing PAYG pension program as the accounts are established. 
Countries that have funded individual accounts by directing revenue 
away from the PAYG program while continuing to pay benefits to PAYG 
program retirees have expanded public debt, built up budget surpluses 
in advance, cut back or eliminated the PAYG programs, or some 
combination of these. Because no individual account program can 
entirely protect against investment risk, some countries have adopted 
individual accounts as a relatively small portion of their national 
pension system. Others set minimum rates of return or provide a minimum 
benefit, which may, however, limit investment diversification and 
individuals’ returns. To mitigate high fees, which can erode small 
account balances, countries have capped fees, centralized the 
processing of transactions, or encouraged price competition. Although 
countries have attempted to educate individuals about reforms and how 
their choices may affect them, some studies indicate that many workers 
have limited knowledge about their retirement prospects. 

www.gao.gov/cgi-bin/getrpt?GAO-05-810T. 

To view the full product, including the scope and methodology, click on 
the link above. For more information, contact Barbara D. Bovbjerg at 
(202) 512-7215 or bovbjergb@gao.gov. 

[End of section]

Mr. Chairman and Members of the Subcommittee: 

I am pleased to be here today to discuss our preliminary findings 
concerning other countries' experiences with national pension reform. 
Many countries, including the United States, are grappling with 
demographic change and its effect on their national pension systems. 
With rising longevity and declining birth rates, the number of workers 
for each retiree is falling in most developed countries. A rising 
dependency ratio is straining the finances of national pension 
programs, particularly programs in which contributions from current 
workers fund payments to current beneficiaries--a form of financing 
known as "pay-as-you-go" (PAYG). Demographic and economic challenges 
are less severe in the U.S. than in many other developed countries--the 
birth rate is not as low, a greater number of older people stay in the 
labor force, and immigration continues to provide young workers. Yet 
projections show that the Social Security program faces a long-term 
financing problem. Because some countries have already undertaken 
national pension reform efforts to address demographic changes similar 
to those occurring in the U.S., we may draw lessons from their 
experiences. It is important to remember, however, that reforms in one 
country may not be easily replicated in another or may not lead to the 
same outcome. 

We are in the process of preparing a report covering the experiences of 
countries that may be applicable to our own debate over reforms to the 
U.S. Social Security program--the 30 members of the Organisation for 
Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD) plus Chile, the nation 
that pioneered the use of individual accounts.[Footnote 1] My remarks 
today are based on an ongoing study and our observations are 
preliminary. We are focusing on (1) adjustments to existing PAYG 
national pension programs, (2) the creation of national pension reserve 
funds to help finance PAYG pension programs, and (3) reforms involving 
the creation of individual accounts. 

To date our study has included interviews with, and analysis of 
materials provided by, officials and interest group representatives in 
Washington, D.C., Paris, and London. We met with pension experts and 
country specialists at the OECD as well as French and British experts, 
officials, and interest group representatives. We conducted our review 
in accordance with generally accepted government auditing standards. 

In summary, all OECD countries have, to some extent, reformed their 
national pension systems, and may offer lessons for the U.S. Countries' 
experiences adjusting PAYG national pension programs highlight the 
importance of considering how modifications will affect the program's 
financial sustainability, its distribution of benefits, the incentives 
it creates, and public understanding of the new provisions. Nearly all 
of the countries we are studying reduced benefits, and most have also 
increased contributions, often by increasing statutory retirement ages. 
Countries with national pension reserve funds designed to partially pre-
fund PAYG pension programs provide lessons about the importance of 
early action and effective management. Some funds that have been in 
place for a long time have accumulated significant reserves to 
strengthen the finances of national pension programs. Countries that 
insulate pension reserve funds from being directed to meet social and 
political objectives may be better equipped to fulfill future pension 
commitments. In addition, regular disclosure of fund performance 
supports sound management and administration, and contributes to public 
education and oversight. Countries that have adopted individual account 
programs--which may also help pre-fund future retirement income--offer 
lessons about financing the existing PAYG pension program as the 
accounts are established. Countries that have funded individual 
accounts by directing revenue away from the PAYG program while 
continuing to pay benefits to PAYG program retirees have expanded 
public debt, built up budget surpluses in advance of the reform, cut 
back or eliminated the PAYG programs, or some combination of these. 
Important lessons regarding the administration of individual accounts 
include the need for effective regulation and supervision of the 
financial industry to protect individuals from avoidable investment 
risks. In addition, public education is increasingly important as the 
national pension system becomes more complex. 

Background: 

Social Security's projected long-term financing shortfall stems 
primarily from the fact that people are living longer and having fewer 
children. As a result, the number of workers paying into the system for 
each beneficiary is projected to decline. This demographic trend is 
occurring or will occur in all OECD countries. Although the number of 
workers for every elderly person in the U.S. has been relatively stable 
over the past few decades, it has already fallen substantially in other 
developed countries. The number of workers for every elderly person in 
the U.S. is projected to fall from 4.1 in 2005 to 2.9 in 2020. In nine 
of the OECD countries, this number has already fallen below the level 
projected for the U.S. in 2020. This rise in the share of the elderly 
in the population could have significant effects on countries' 
economies, particularly during the period from 2010 to 2030. These 
effects may include slower economic growth and increased costs for 
aging-related government programs. 

Historically, developed countries have relied on some form of a PAYG 
program and have used a variety of approaches to reform their national 
pension systems.[Footnote 2] In many cases, these approaches provide a 
basic or minimum benefit as well as a benefit based on the level of a 
worker's earnings. Several countries are preparing to pay future 
benefits by either supplementing or replacing their PAYG programs. For 
example, some have set aside and invested current resources in a 
national pension reserve fund to partially pre-fund their PAYG program. 
Some have established fully funded individual accounts. These are not 
mutually exclusive types of reform. In fact, many countries have 
undertaken more than one of the following types of reform: 

* Adjustments to existing pay-as-you-go systems. Typically, these are 
designed to create a more sustainable program by increasing 
contributions or decreasing benefits, or both, while preserving the 
basic structure of the system. Measures include phasing in higher 
retirement ages, equalizing retirement ages across genders, and 
increasing the earnings period over which initial benefits are 
calculated. Some countries have created notional defined contribution 
(NDC) accounts for each worker, which tie benefits more closely to each 
worker's contributions and to factors such as the growth rate of the 
economy. 

* National pension reserve funds. These are set up to partially pre- 
fund PAYG national pension programs. Governments commit to make regular 
transfers to these investment funds from, for example, budgetary 
surpluses. To the extent that these contribute to national saving, they 
reduce the need for future borrowing or large increases in contribution 
rates to pay scheduled benefits. Funds can be invested in a combination 
of government securities and domestic as well as foreign 
equities.[Footnote 3]

* Individual accounts. These fully funded accounts are administered 
either by employers or the government or designated third parties. The 
level of retirement benefits depends largely on the amount of each 
person's contributions into the account during their working life, 
investment earnings, and the amount of fees they are required to pay. 

We are applying GAO's Social Security reform criteria to the 
experiences of countries that are members of the OECD as well as Chile, 
which pioneered individual accounts in 1981. We are assessing both the 
extent to which another country's circumstances are similar enough to 
those in the U.S. to provide a useful example and the extent to which 
particular approaches to pension reform were considered to be 
successful. Countries have different starting points, including unique 
economic and political environments. Moreover availability of other 
sources of retirement income, such as occupation-based pensions, varies 
greatly. Recognizing this, GAO uses three criteria for evaluating 
pension reforms: 

* Financing Sustainable Solvency. We are looking at the extent to which 
particular reforms influence the funds available to pay benefits and 
how the reforms affect the ability of the economy, the government's 
budget, and national savings to support the program on a continuing 
basis. 

* Balancing Equity and Adequacy. We are examining the relative balance 
struck between the goals of allowing individuals to receive a fair 
return on their contributions and ensuring an adequate level of 
benefits to prevent dependency and poverty. 

* Implementing and Administering Reforms. We are considering how easily 
a reform is implemented and administered and how the public is educated 
concerning the reform. 

Because each country is introducing reforms in a unique demographic, 
economic, and political context these factors will likely affect reform 
choices and outcomes. For instance, several European countries we are 
reviewing have strong occupation-based pension programs that contribute 
to retirement income security. In addition, some countries had more 
generous national pensions and other programs supporting the elderly 
than others. All countries also provide benefits for survivors and the 
disabled; often these are funded separately from old age benefit 
programs. Some countries are carrying out reforms against a backdrop of 
broader national change. For example, Hungary and Poland were 
undergoing large political and economic transformations as they 
reformed their national pension systems. All of these issues should be 
considered when drawing lessons. 

In addition to the adjustments that countries have made to their 
existing PAYG systems, many countries have undergone other changes as 
well, indicating that change may not be a one-time experience. (See 
table 1.) Understanding the outcomes of a country's reform requires us 
to look at all of the changes a country has made. 

Table 1: Countries' National Pension Reforms: 

Only adjustments to PAYG: 
Austria; 
Czech Republic[B]; 
Italy; 
Germany[C]; 
Turkey.

Adjustments to PAYG and National Pension Fund: 
Belgium; 
Canada; 
Finland; 
France; 
Greece; 
Ireland; 
Japan; 
Korea; 
Luxembourg; 
Netherlands; 
New Zealand; 
Portugal; 
Norway; 
Spain; 
U.S. 

Adjustments to PAYG and Individual Accounts: 
Australia; 
Chile[D]; 
Hungary; 
Iceland[E]; 
Mexico; 
Poland; 
Slovak Republic; 
UK[F].

All Three Types: 
Denmark; 
Sweden; 
Switzerland[G].

Source: OECD, International Social Security Association, and the Social 
Security Administration. 

[A] Member nations of the OECD and Chile. 

[B] The Czech Republic's defined contribution account program is not 
included as an "individual account reform" as it is a voluntary 
supplementary program. For a discussion of these accounts, see U.S. 
General Accounting Office, Social Security Reform: Information on Using 
a Voluntary Approach to Individual Accounts, GAO-03-309 (Washington, 
D.C.: Mar. 10, 2003), p. 46-54. 

[C] Germany's Riester pension program is not included as an individual 
account reform because it is a supplement to the mandatory national 
pension program, rather than an alternative. For a discussion of these 
accounts, see U.S. General Accounting Office, Social Security Reform: 
Information on Using a Voluntary Approach to Individual Accounts, GAO- 
03-309 (Washington, D.C.: Mar. 10, 2003), p. 55-63. 

[D] Chile is not an OECD country, but was included in our study because 
it pioneered individual account reforms. 

[E] Iceland's mandatory occupation-based pension program allows for the 
creation of defined contribution individual accounts as a complement to 
defined benefit pensions. However, in practice, employers have not yet 
established these. Voluntary supplementary individual accounts are also 
available. 

[F] The UK requires either participation in a state earnings-related 
pension program or an approved alternative including individual 
accounts. 

[G] Switzerland's mandatory occupation-based pensions provide 
individual accounts that accrue credits at at least a minimum 
prescribed interest rate. 

[End of table]

Adjustments to Existing PAYG Programs Show Importance of 
Sustainability, Safety Nets, and Incentives to Work and Save: 

The experiences of the countries that have adjusted their existing PAYG 
national pension programs highlight the importance of considering how 
modifications will affect the program's financial sustainability, its 
distribution of benefits, the incentives it creates, and the extent to 
which the public understands the new provisions. 

PAYG Adjustments Prove Important to Financial Sustainability: 

To reconcile PAYG program revenue and expenses, nearly all the 
countries we studied have decreased benefits and most have also 
increased contributions, often in part by increasing retirement ages. 
Generally countries with national pension programs that are relatively 
financially sustainable have undertaken a package of several far- 
reaching adjustments. The countries we are studying increased 
contributions to PAYG programs by raising contribution rates, 
increasing the range of earnings or kinds of earnings subject to 
contribution requirements, or increasing the retirement age. Most of 
these countries increased contribution rates for some or all workers. 
Canada, for example, increased contributions to its Canadian Pension 
Plan from a total of 5.85 percent to 9.9 percent of wages, half paid by 
employers and half by employees. Several countries, including the UK, 
increased contributions by expanding the range of earnings subject to 
contributions requirements. 

Nearly all of the countries we are studying decreased scheduled 
benefits, using a wide range of techniques. Some techniques reduce the 
level of initial benefits; others reduce the rate at which benefits 
increase during retirement or adjust benefits based on retirees' 
financial means. 

* Increased years of earnings. To reduce initial benefits several 
countries increased the number of years of earnings they consider in 
calculating an average lifetime earnings level. France previously based 
its calculation on 10 years, but increased this to 25 years for its 
basic public program. 

* Increased minimum years of contributions. Another approach is to 
increase the minimum number of years of contributions required to 
receive a full benefit. France increased the required number of years 
from 37.5 to 40 years. Belgium is increasing its minimum requirement 
for early retirement from 20 to 35 years. 

* Changed formula for calculating benefits. Another approach to 
decreasing the initial benefit is to change the formula for adjusting 
prior years' earnings. Countries with traditional PAYG programs all 
make some adjustment to the nominal amount of wages earned previously 
to reflect changes in prices or wages over the intervening years. 
Although most of the countries we are studying use some kind of average 
wage index, others, including Belgium and France, have adopted the use 
of price indices. The choice of a wage or price index can have quite 
different effects depending on the rate at which wages increase in 
comparison to prices. We see variation in the extent to which wages 
outpace prices over time and among countries. 

* Changed basis for determining year-to-year increases in benefits. In 
many of the countries we are studying, the rate at which monthly 
retirement benefits increase from year-to-year during retirement is 
based on increases in prices, which generally rise more slowly than 
earnings. Others, including Denmark, Ireland, Luxembourg, and the 
Netherlands, use increases in earnings or a combination of wage and 
price indices. Hungary, for example, changed from the use of a wage 
index to the Swiss method--an index weighted 50 percent on price 
changes and 50 percent on changes in earnings. 

* Implemented provisions that provide a closer link between pension 
contributions and benefits. Countries that have adopted this approach 
stop promising a defined level of benefits and instead keep track of 
notional contributions into workers' NDC accounts. Unlike individual 
accounts, these notional defined accounts are not funded. Current 
contributions to the program continue to be used largely to pay 
benefits to current workers, while at the same time they are credited 
to individuals' notional accounts. When these programs include 
adjustments that link benefits to factors such as economic growth, 
longevity, and/or the ratio of workers to retirees, they may contribute 
to the financial sustainability of national pension systems. 

Several countries, such as Sweden and the UK, have undertaken one or 
more of these adjustments to their PAYG programs and have achieved, or 
are on track to achieve relative financial sustainability. Others, 
including Japan, France, and Germany, may need additional reforms to 
fund future benefit commitments. 

Maintenance of a Safety Net and Work and Saving Incentives Proved 
Important: 

All of the countries have included in their reforms provisions to 
ensure adequate benefits for lower-income groups and put into place 
programs designed to ensure that all qualified retirees have a minimum 
level of income. Most do so by providing a targeted means-tested 
program that provides more benefits to retirees with limited financial 
means. Two countries--Germany and Italy--provide retirees access to 
general social welfare programs that are available to people of all 
ages rather than programs with different provisions for elderly people. 

Twelve countries use another approach to providing a safety net: a 
basic retirement benefit. The level of the benefit is either a given 
amount per month for all retirees or an amount based on years of 
contributions to the program. In Ireland, for example, workers who 
contribute to the program for a specified period receive a minimum 
pension. Chile set a minimum pension equal to the minimum wage--about 
one-quarter of average earnings as of 2005. In addition, several of the 
countries we are studying give very low-income workers credit for a 
minimum level contribution. Other countries give workers credit for 
years in which they were unemployed, pursued postsecondary education, 
or cared for dependents. 

In selecting between the many reform options, policy makers need to 
strike a careful balance among the following objectives: provide a 
safety net, contain costs, and maintain incentives to work and save. 
Costs can be high if a generous basic pension is provided to all 
eligible retirees regardless of their income. On the other hand, means- 
tested benefits can diminish incentives to work and save. The UK 
provides both a basic state pension and a means-tested pension credit. 
Concerned about the decline in the proportion of preretirement earnings 
provided by the basic state pension, some have advocated making it more 
generous. Others argue that focusing safety-net spending on those in 
need enables the government to alleviate pensioner poverty in a cost 
effective manner. However, a guaranteed minimum income could reduce 
some peoples' incentive to save. In view of this disincentive, the UK 
adopted an additional means-tested benefit that provides higher 
benefits for retirees near the minimum income level. This benefit, 
called the savings credit, allows low-income retirees near the minimum 
pension level to retain a portion of their additional income. However, 
any loss of income due to means-testing still diminishes incentives to 
save. Without changes to pension rules, the proportion of pensioners 
eligible for means-tested income is expected to increase to include 
almost 65 percent of retiree households by 2050. 

Implementation, Administration, and Public Education Are Important: 

The extent to which new provisions are implemented, administered, and 
explained to the public may affect the outcome of the reform. Poland, 
for example, adopted NDC reform in 1999, but the development of a data 
system to track contributions has been problematic. As of early 2004, 
the system generated statements indicating contributions workers made 
during 2002, but there was no indication of what workers contributed in 
earlier years or to previous pension programs. Without knowing how much 
they have in their notional defined accounts, workers may have a 
difficult time planning for their retirement. Some governments have had 
limited success in efforts to educate workers about changes in 
provisions that will affect their retirement income. For example, a 
survey of women in the UK showed that only about 43 percent of women 
who will be affected by an increase in the retirement age knew the age 
that applied to them. 

Early Action and Effective Management Help Make National Pension 
Reserve Funds Successful: 

Another type of pension reform is the accumulation of reserves in 
national pension funds, which can contribute to the system's financial 
sustainability depending on when the funds are created or reformed and 
how they are managed. Countries that chose to partially pre-fund their 
PAYG programs decades ago have had more time to amass substantial 
reserves, reducing the risk that they will not meet their pension 
obligations. A record of poor fund performance has led some countries 
to put reserve funds under the administration of relatively independent 
managers with the mandate to maximize returns without undue risk. 

Early Action Matters: 

Establishing reserve funds ahead of demographic changes--well before 
the share of elderly in the population increases substantially--makes 
it more likely that enough assets will accumulate to meet future 
pension obligations. In countries such as Sweden, Denmark, and Finland, 
which have had long experiences with partial pre-funding of PAYG 
programs, important reserves have already built up. These resources are 
expected to make significant contributions to the long-term finances of 
national pension programs. Other countries that have recently created 
pension reserve funds for their pension program have a tighter time 
frame to accumulate enough reserves before population aging starts 
straining public finances. In particular, the imminent retirement of 
the baby-boom generation is likely to make it challenging to continue 
channeling a substantial amount of resources to these funds. France, 
for example, relies primarily on social security surpluses to finance 
its pension reserve fund set up in 1999, but given its demographic 
trends, may be able to do so only in the next few years. Similarly, 
Belgium and the Netherlands plan on maintaining a budget surplus, 
reducing public debt and the interest payments associated with the 
debt, and transferring these earmarked resources to their reserve 
funds. However, maintaining a surplus will require sustained budgetary 
discipline as a growing number of retirees begins putting pressure on 
public finances. 

Effective Management Can Contribute to Financial Sustainability: 

Examples from several countries reveal that pre-funding with national 
pension reserve funds is less likely to be effective in helping ensure 
that national pension programs are financially sustainable if these 
funds are used for purposes other than supporting the PAYGO program. 
Some countries have used funds to pursue industrial, economic, or 
social objectives. For example, Japan used its reserve fund to support 
infrastructure projects, provide housing and education loans, and 
subsidize small and medium enterprises. As a result, Japan compromised 
to some extent the principal goal of pre-funding. 

Past experiences have also highlighted the need to mitigate certain 
risks that pension reserve funds face. One kind of risk has to do with 
the fact that asset build-up in a fund may lead to competing pressures 
for tax cuts and spending increases, especially when a fund is 
integrated in the national budget. For example, governments may view 
fund resources as a ready source of credit. As a result, they may be 
inclined to spend more than they would otherwise, potentially 
undermining the purpose of pre-funding. Ireland alleviated the risk 
that its reserve fund could raise government consumption by prohibiting 
investment of fund assets in domestic government bonds. 

Another risk is the pressure that groups may exert on the investment 
choices of a pension reserve fund, potentially lowering returns. For 
example, Canada and Japan have requirements to invest a minimum share 
of their fund portfolio in domestic assets, restricting holdings of 
foreign assets to stimulate economic development at home. Funds in 
several countries have also faced pressure to adopt ethical investment 
criteria, with possible negative impacts on returns. In recent years, 
some countries have taken steps to ensure that funds are managed to 
maximize returns, without undue risk. Canada, for example, has put its 
fund under the control of an independent Investment Board operating at 
arm's length from the government since the late 1990's. Several 
countries, including New Zealand, have taken steps to provide regular 
reports and more complete disclosures concerning pension reserve funds. 

Individual Account Reforms Show the Importance of Funding Decisions and 
Ensuring Benefit Adequacy: 

Countries that have adopted individual account programs--which may also 
help pre-fund future retirement income--offer lessons about financing 
the existing PAYG pension program as the accounts are established. Some 
countries manage this transition period by expanding public debt, 
building up budget surpluses in advance of implementation, reducing or 
eliminating the PAYG program, or some combination of these. In 
addition, administering individual accounts requires effective 
regulation and supervision of the financial industry to protect 
individuals from avoidable investment risks. Educating the public is 
also important as national pension systems become more complex. 

Approach to Funding Individual Accounts Affects Sustainability of 
National Pension System: 

It is important to consider how different approaches to including 
individual accounts may affect the short-term and long-term financing 
of the national pension system and the economy as a whole. A common 
challenge faced by countries that adopt individual accounts is how to 
pay for both a new funded pension and an existing PAYG pension 
simultaneously, known as transition costs. Countries will encounter 
transition costs depending on whether the individual accounts redirect 
revenue from the existing PAYG program, the amount of revenue 
redirected, and how liabilities under the existing PAYG program are 
treated. 

The countries we are examining offer a range of approaches for 
including individual accounts and dealing with the prospective 
transition costs. Australia and Switzerland avoided transition costs 
altogether by adding individual accounts to their existing national 
pension systems, which are modest relative to those in the other 
countries we are studying.[Footnote 4] Some countries diverted revenue 
from the existing PAYG program to the individual accounts. The 
resulting shortfall reflects, in part, the portion of the PAYG program 
being replaced with individual accounts and the amount of PAYG revenue 
being redirected to fund the accounts. For example, transition costs 
may be less in countries such as Sweden or Denmark where the 
contribution to individual accounts is 2.5 percent of covered earnings 
and 1 percent, respectively, than for Poland or Hungary, which replaced 
a larger portion of the PAYG program. 

All of the countries we are reviewing also made changes to their PAYG 
program that were meant to help reduce transition costs, such as 
increasing taxes or decreasing benefits. In addition, Chile built a 
surplus in anticipation of major pension reform, and Sweden had large 
budget surpluses in place prior to establishing individual accounts. 
Countries also transfer funds from general budget revenues to help pay 
benefits to current and near retirees, expanding public borrowing. If 
individual accounts are financed through borrowing they will not 
positively affect national saving until the debt is repaid, as 
contributions to individual accounts are offset by increased public 
debt.[Footnote 5] For example, Poland's debt is expected to exceed 60 
percent of GDP in the next few years in part because of its public 
borrowing to pay for the movement to individual accounts. 

It is sometimes difficult for countries to predict their transition 
costs. In particular, countries that allow workers to opt in or out of 
individual account programs have had difficulty estimating costs. For 
example, Hungary and Poland experienced higher than anticipated 
enrollment from current workers in their individual account programs, 
leaving the existing PAYG program with less funding than planned. As a 
result, both countries had to make subsequent changes to their 
individual account and PAYG programs. 

Balancing Opportunities to Realize High Returns and Benefit Adequacy Is 
Important: 

Countries adopting individual accounts as part of their national 
pension system have had to make trade-offs between giving workers the 
opportunity to maximize returns in their accounts and ensuring that 
benefits will be adequate for all participants. Some countries set a 
guaranteed rate of return to reduce certain investment risks and help 
ensure adequacy of benefits. These guarantees may, however, result in 
limited investment diversification with a potentially negative impact 
on returns. In Chile, for example, fund managers' performance is 
measured against the returns of other funds. This has resulted in a 
"herding" effect because funds hold similar portfolios, reducing 
meaningful choice for workers. All the countries with individual 
accounts provide some form of a minimum guaranteed benefit so retirees 
will have at least some level of income. Some experts believe that a 
minimum pension guarantee could raise a moral hazard whereby 
individuals may make risky investment decisions, minimize voluntary 
contributions, or, as in the case of Australia where the minimum 
guarantee is means-tested, may spend down their retirement assets 
quickly. 

It is important to consider the payout options available from 
individual accounts, as these can also have substantial effects on 
adequacy of income throughout retirement. For example, an annuity 
payout option can help to ensure that individuals will not outlive 
their assets in retirement.[Footnote 6] However, purchasing an annuity 
can leave some people worse off if, for example, the annuities market 
is not fully developed, premiums are high, or inflation erodes the 
purchasing power of benefits. Several countries also allow for phased 
withdrawals, in some cases with restrictions, helping to mitigate the 
risk of individuals outliving their assets and becoming reliant on the 
government's basic or safety-net pension. Some countries offer a lump- 
sum payment under certain circumstances, such as small account 
balances, and Australia allows a full lump-sum payout for all retirees. 

Effective Regulation, Implementation, and Education Can Protect 
Individuals: 

Important lessons can be learned regarding the administration of 
individual accounts, including the need for effective regulation and 
supervision of the financial industry to protect individuals from 
avoidable investment risks. Some countries have expanded their 
permitted investment options to include foreign investments and 
increased the percentage of assets that can be invested in private 
equities. The experiences of countries we are studying also indicate 
the importance of keeping administrative fees and charges under 
control. The fees that countries permit pension funds to charge can 
have a big influence on the amount of income retirees receive from 
their individual accounts. Several countries have limits on the level 
and types of fees providers can charge. Additionally, the level of fees 
should take into consideration the potential impact not only on 
individuals' accounts, but also on fund managers. In the UK, for 
example, regulations capping fees may have discouraged some providers 
from offering pension funds. To keep costs low, Sweden aggregates 
individuals' transactions to realize economies of scale. 

Some countries' experiences highlighted weaknesses in regulations on 
how pension funds can market to individuals. The UK's and Poland's 
regulations did not prevent problems in marketing and sales. Poland 
experienced sales problems, in part because it had inadequate training 
and standards for its sales agents, which may have contributed to 
agents' use of questionable practices to sign up individuals. The UK 
had a widely-publicized "mis-selling" scandal involving millions of 
investors. Many opened individual accounts when they would more likely 
have been better off retaining their occupation-based pension. 
Insurance companies were ordered to pay roughly $20 billion in 
compensation. 

Countries' individual account experiences reveal pitfalls to be avoided 
during implementation. For example, Hungary, Poland, and Sweden had 
difficulty getting their data management systems to run properly and 
continue to experience a substantial lag time in recording 
contributions to individuals' accounts. In addition, Hungary and Poland 
did not have an annuities market that offered the type of annuity 
required by legislation. 

Education becomes increasingly important as the national pension 
systems become more complex. It is particularly important for workers 
who may have to make a one-time decision about joining the individual 
account program. Several countries require disclosure statements about 
the status of a pension fund, and some provide annual statements. To 
help individuals choose a fund manager, one important component of 
these statements should be the disclosure of fees charged. Some 
countries have done a better job of providing fund performance 
information than others. For example, Australia requires its fund 
providers to inform members through annual reports clearly detailing 
benefits, fees and charges, investment strategy, and the fund's 
financial position. In contrast, Hungary did not have clear rules for 
disclosing operating costs and returns, making it hard to compare fund 
performance. 

Concluding Observations: 

Demographic challenges and fiscal pressure have necessitated national 
pension reform in many countries. Though one common goal behind reform 
efforts everywhere is to improve financial sustainability, countries 
have adopted different approaches depending on their existing national 
pension system and the prevailing economic and political conditions. 
This is why reforms in one country are not easily replicated in 
another, or if they are, may not lead to the same outcome. Countries 
have different emphases, such as benefit adequacy or individual equity; 
as a result, what is perceived to be successful in one place may not be 
viewed as a viable option somewhere else. 

Although some pension reforms were undertaken too recently to provide 
clear evidence of results, the experiences of other countries may 
suggest some lessons for U.S. deliberations on Social Security reform. 
Some of these lessons are common to all types of national pension 
reform and are consistent with findings in previous GAO studies. 
Restoring long-term financial balance invariably involves cutting 
benefits, raising revenues, or both. Additionally, with early reform, 
policy makers can avoid the need for more costly and difficult changes 
later. Countries that undertook important national pension reform well 
before undergoing major demographic changes have achieved, or are close 
to achieving, financially sustainable national pension systems. Others 
are likely to need more significant steps because their populations are 
already aging. 

No matter what type of reform is undertaken, the sustainability of a 
pension system will depend on the health of the national economy. As 
the number of working people for each retiree declines, average output 
per worker must increase in order to sustain average standards of 
living. Reforms that encourage employment and saving, offer incentives 
to postpone retirement, and promote growth are more likely to produce a 
pension system that delivers adequate retirement income and is 
financially sound for the long term. 

Regardless of a country's approach, its institutions need to 
effectively operate and supervise the different aspects of reform. A 
government's capacity to implement and administer the publicly managed 
elements of reform and its ability to regulate and oversee the 
privately managed components are crucial. In addition, education of the 
public becomes increasingly important as workers and retirees face more 
choices and the national pension system becomes more complex. This is 
particularly true in the case of individual account reforms, which 
require higher levels of financial literacy and personal 
responsibility. 

In nearly every country we are studying, debate continues about 
alternatives for additional reform measures. It is clearly not a 
process that ends with one reform. This may be true in part because 
success can only be measured over the long term, but problems may arise 
and need to be dealt with in the short term. The positive lessons from 
other countries' reforms may only truly be clear in years to come. 

Mr. Chairman and Members of the Subcommittee, this concludes my 
prepared statement. I'd be happy to answer any questions you may have. 

GAO Contacts and Staff Acknowledgments: 

For further information regarding this testimony, please contact 
Barbara D. Bovbjerg, Director, Education, Workforce, and Income 
Security Issues at (202) 512-7215. Alicia Puente Cackley, Assistant 
Director, Benjamin P. Pfeiffer, Thomas A. Moscovitch, Nyree M. Ryder, 
Seyda G. Wentworth and Corinna A. Nicolaou, also contributed to this 
report. 

FOOTNOTES

[1] The OECD is a forum for the governments of 30 market democracies to 
work together on economic, social, environmental, and governance 
issues. The OECD works to promote economic growth, financial stability, 
trade and investment, technology, innovation, and development co- 
operation. 

[2] In other countries, "social security" often refers to a wide range 
of social insurance programs, including health care, long-term care, 
workers' compensation, unemployment insurance, etc. To generalize 
across countries, we use "national pensions" to refer to mandatory 
countrywide pension programs providing old-age pensions. We use "Social 
Security" to refer to the U.S. Old-Age, Survivors, and Disability 
Insurance Program since that is how the program is commonly known. 

[3] Reserve funds act as budgetary devices, or "disciplinary" devices, 
especially where they have been recently created. They help contain 
expenditures. Such containment is needed to achieve sustainable fiscal 
surplus. 

[4] Australia's national PAYG program consistently replaces 
approximately 25 percent of average wages (23 percent in 2005); 
Switzerland's national PAYG program replaced approximately 26 percent 
of average wages in 2005. 

[5] Additionally, increased government debt may crowd out private 
sector access to lending markets and dampen the economic growth 
individual accounts are meant to access. 

[6] The countries we reviewed require a range of annuity options, 
including, for example, inflation indexed, joint and survivor, or 
gender-neutral.