This is the accessible text file for GAO report number GAO-05-318T 
entitled Long-Term Fiscal Issues: The Need for Social Security Reform' 
which was released on February 9, 2005.

This text file was formatted by the U.S. Government Accountability 
Office (GAO) to be accessible to users with visual impairments, as part 
of a longer term project to improve GAO products' accessibility. Every 
attempt has been made to maintain the structural and data integrity of 
the original printed product. Accessibility features, such as text 
descriptions of tables, consecutively numbered footnotes placed at the 
end of the file, and the text of agency comment letters, are provided 
but may not exactly duplicate the presentation or format of the printed 
version. The portable document format (PDF) file is an exact electronic 
replica of the printed version. We welcome your feedback. Please E-mail 
your comments regarding the contents or accessibility features of this 
document to Webmaster@gao.gov.

This is a work of the U.S. government and is not subject to copyright 
protection in the United States. It may be reproduced and distributed 
in its entirety without further permission from GAO. Because this work 
may contain copyrighted images or other material, permission from the 
copyright holder may be necessary if you wish to reproduce this 
material separately.

Testimony:

Before the Committee on the Budget, House of Representatives:

For Release on Delivery Expected at 10:00 a.m. EST Wednesday, February 
9, 2005:

Long-Term Fiscal Issues:

The Need for Social Security Reform:

Statement of David M. Walker: 
Comptroller General of the United States:

[Hyperlink, http://www.gao.gov/cgi-bin/getrpt?GAO-05-318T]:

GAO Highlights:

Highlights of GAO-05-318T, a testimony before the Budget Committee, 
House of Representatives: 

Why GAO Did This Study:

Social Security is the foundation of the nation’s retirement income 
system, helping to protect the vast majority of American workers and 
their families from poverty in old age. However, it is much more than a 
retirement program, providing millions of Americans with disability 
insurance and survivors’ benefits. As the baby boom generation retires 
and given longer life spans and lower birth rates, Social Security’s 
financing shortfall will grow. The current gap between promised and 
funded benefits is $3.7 trillion and is growing daily. 

The Chairman of the House Budget Committee asked GAO to discuss the 
need for Social Security reform. This testimony addresses the nature of 
Social Security’s long-term financing problem and why it is preferable 
for Congress to take action sooner rather than later. This testimony 
also notes the broader context in which reform proposals should be 
considered and the criteria that GAO has recommended as a basis for 
analyzing any Social Security reform proposals.

What GAO Found:

Although the Social Security system is not in crisis today, it faces a 
serious and growing solvency and sustainability challenge that is 
growing as time passes. If we did nothing until 2042, achieving 
actuarial balance would require a 30-percent reduction in benefits or a 
43-percent increase in payroll taxes. Furthermore, Social Security’s 
problems are a subset of our nation’s overall fiscal challenge. Absent 
reform, the nation will ultimately have to choose among escalating 
federal deficits and debt, huge tax increases and/or dramatic budget 
cuts. As GAO’s long-term budget simulations show, substantive reform of 
Social Security and our major federal health programs (e.g., Medicare 
and Medicaid) is critical to saving our fiscal future. Taking action 
soon would also serve to reduce the amount of change needed to ensure 
that Social Security is solvent, sustainable, and secure for current 
and future generations. Acting sooner would also serve to improve the 
federal government’s credibility with the markets and the confidence of 
the American people in the government’s ability to address long-range 
challenges before they reach crisis proportions. 

However, financial stability should not be the only consideration when 
evaluating reform proposals. Other important objectives, such as 
balancing the adequacy and equity of the benefits structure and various 
administrative and operational issues need to be considered. 
Furthermore, any changes to Social Security should be considered in the 
context of the broader challenges facing our nation, such as the 
changing nature of the private pension system, escalating health care 
costs, and the need to reform Medicare and Medicaid.

Composition of Spending as a Share of Gross Domestic Product (GDP) 
Assuming Discretionary Spending Grows with GDP after 2005 and All 
Expiring Tax Provisions Are Extended: 

[See PDF for image]

[End of figure]

www.gao.gov/cgi-bin/getrpt?GAO-05-318T.

To view the full product, including the scope and methodology, click on 
the link above. For more information, contact Susan Irving at (202) 
512-9142 or irvings@gao.gov.

[End of section]

Mr. Chairman and Members of the Committee:

I appreciate the opportunity to talk with you about our nation's Social 
Security program[Footnote 1] and how to address the challenges 
presented in ensuring the long-term viability of this important social 
insurance system. Social Security provides a foundation of retirement 
income for millions of Americans and has prevented many former workers 
and their families from living their retirement years in poverty. 
Fixing Social Security is about more than finances. It is also about 
maintaining an adequate safety net for American workers against loss of 
income from retirement, disability, or death.

As I have said in congressional testimonies over the past several 
years, the Social Security system faces both solvency and 
sustainability challenges in the longer term.[Footnote 2] While the 
Social Security program does not face an immediate crisis, it does have 
a $3.7 trillion gap between promised and funded benefits in current 
dollar terms. This gap is growing daily and, given this and other major 
fiscal challenges including expected growth in federal health spending, 
it would be prudent to act sooner rather than later to reform the 
Social Security program. Failure to take steps to address our large and 
structural long-range fiscal imbalance, which is driven in large part 
by projected increases in Medicare, Medicaid, and Social Security 
spending, will ultimately have significant adverse consequences for our 
country, children, and grandchildren.

Let me begin by highlighting a number of important points concerning 
the Social Security challenge and our broader fiscal and economic 
challenge.

* Solving Social Security's long-term financing problem is more 
important and complex than simply making the numbers add up. Social 
Security is an important and successful social insurance program that 
affects virtually every American family. It currently pays benefits to 
more than 47 million people, including retired workers, disabled 
workers, the spouses and children of retired and disabled workers, and 
the survivors of deceased workers. The number of individuals receiving 
benefits is expected to grow to almost 69 million by 2020. The program 
has been highly effective at reducing the incidence of poverty among 
the elderly, and the disability and survivor benefits have been 
critical to the financial well-being of millions of others.

* Social Security reform is part of a broader fiscal and economic 
challenge. If you look ahead in the federal budget, Social Security 
together with the rapidly growing health programs (Medicare and 
Medicaid) will dominate the federal government's future fiscal outlook. 
While this hearing is not about the complexities of Medicare, it is 
important to note that Medicare presents a much greater, more complex, 
and more urgent fiscal challenge than Social Security. Medicare growth 
rates reflect not only a burgeoning beneficiary population, but also 
the escalation of health care costs at rates well exceeding general 
rates of inflation. Taken together, Social Security, Medicare, and 
Medicaid represent an unsustainable burden on future generations. 
Furthermore, any changes to Social Security should be considered in the 
context of the problems currently facing our nation's private pension 
system. These include the chronically low level of coverage of the 
private workforce, the continued decline in defined benefit plans 
coupled with the termination of large underfunded plans by bankrupt 
firms, and the shift by employers to defined contribution plans, where 
workers face the potential for greater return but also assume greater 
financial risk.

* Focusing on trust fund solvency alone is not sufficient. We need to 
put the program on a path toward sustainable solvency. Trust fund 
solvency is an important concept, but focusing on trust fund solvency 
alone can lead to a false sense of security about the overall condition 
of the Social Security program. After all, the Social Security Trust 
Fund is a subaccount of the federal government rather than a private 
trust fund. Its assets are not readily marketable nor are they 
convertible into cash other than through raising revenues, cutting 
other government expenses, or increasing debt held by the public. 
Furthermore, the size of the trust fund does not tell us whether the 
program is sustainable--that is, whether the government will have the 
capacity to pay future claims or what else will have to be squeezed to 
pay those claims. Aiming for sustainable solvency would increase the 
chance that future policymakers would not have to face these difficult 
questions on a recurring basis. Estimates of what it would take to 
achieve 75-year trust fund solvency understate the extent of the 
problem because the program's financial imbalance gets worse in the 
76th and subsequent years.

* Acting sooner rather than later helps to ease the difficulty of 
change. The challenge of facing the imminent and daunting budget 
pressure from Medicare, Medicaid, and Social Security increases over 
time. Social Security will begin to constrain the budget long before 
the trust fund is exhausted in 2042. The Social Security cash surpluses 
that are now helping to finance the rest of the government's budgetary 
needs will begin to decline in 2008, and by 2018, the cash surpluses 
will turn to deficits. Social Security's cash shortfall will place 
increasing pressure on the rest of the budget to raise the resources 
necessary to meet the program's costs. Waiting until Social Security 
faces an immediate trust fund solvency crisis will limit the scope of 
feasible solutions and could reduce the options to only those choices 
that are the most difficult. It could also contribute to a further 
delay of the really tough decisions on federal health programs. Acting 
sooner rather than later would allow changes to be more modest while 
also being phased in so that future retirees will have time to adjust 
their retirement planning. Furthermore, acting sooner rather than later 
would serve to increase our credibility with the markets and improve 
the public's confidence in the federal government's ability to deal 
with our significant long-range fiscal challenges before they reach 
crisis proportions.

* Reform proposals should be evaluated as packages. The elements of any 
reform proposal interact; every package will have pluses and minuses, 
and no plan will satisfy everyone on all dimensions. If we focus on the 
pros and cons of each element of reform by itself, we may find it 
impossible to build the bridges necessary to achieve consensus. 
Analyses of reform proposals should reflect the fact that the program 
faces a long-term actuarial deficit and that benefit reduction and/or 
revenue increases will be necessary to restore solvency. This requires 
looking at proposed reforms from at least two perspectives or 
benchmarks--one that raises revenue to fund currently scheduled 
benefits (promised benefits) and one that adjusts benefits to a level 
supported by current tax financing (funded benefits).

Today, the Social Security program does not face an immediate crisis, 
but rather a long-range financing problem driven by demographic trends. 
While the crisis is not immediate, the challenge is more urgent than it 
may appear since the program will experience increasing negative cash 
flow starting in 2018. Acting soon to address these problems reduces 
the likelihood that Congress will have to choose between imposing 
severe benefit cuts and unfairly burdening future generations with the 
program's rising costs. Acting soon would also allow changes to be 
phased in so the individuals who are most likely to be affected, namely 
younger and future workers, will have time to adjust their retirement 
planning while helping to avoid related "expectation gaps." On the 
other hand, failure to take remedial action will, in combination with 
other entitlement spending, lead to a situation unsustainable both for 
the federal government and, ultimately, the economy.

Today we have an opportunity to address the relatively easier part of 
the overall entitlement challenge before the baby boom generation 
begins to retire and the challenge begins to compound. Medicare 
represents a much larger driver of the long-term fiscal outlook, but 
this does not mean that Social Security reform should be postponed 
until after it is addressed. On the contrary, it argues for moving 
ahead on Social Security soon. Unlike the case in health care, 
potential approaches to Social Security reform have already been 
articulated in various proposals in recent years. These approaches can 
serve as a starting point for deliberations. Since health care will be 
much harder to address, there is a significant danger that if we do not 
move ahead on Social Security now, we could end up reforming neither. 
Successful Social Security reform could also help build both trust and 
confidence and thereby facilitate consideration of the needed 
structural changes in the health care system.

The Social Security system has required changes in the past to ensure 
its future solvency. Congress took action to address an immediate 
solvency crisis in 1983. While such an immediate crisis will not occur 
for many years, waiting until it is imminent will not be prudent. 
Furthermore, I believe it is possible to craft a solution that will 
protect Social Security benefits for the nation's current and near-term 
retirees, while ensuring that the system will be there for future 
generations. I believe that it is possible to reform Social Security in 
a way that will assure the program's solvency and sustainability while 
exceeding the expectations of all generations of Americans.

Social Security Reform Is Part of a Broader Fiscal and Economic 
Challenge:

In my role as lead partner on the audit of the U.S. government's 
consolidated financial statements and the de facto Chief Accountability 
Officer of the United States government, I have become increasingly 
concerned about the state of our nation's finances. In speeches and 
presentations over the past several years, I have called attention to 
our large and growing long-term fiscal challenge and the risks it poses 
to our nation's future.[Footnote 3] Simply put, our nation's fiscal 
policy is on an unsustainable course, and our long-term fiscal 
imbalance worsened significantly in 2004. GAO's simulations--as well as 
those of the Congressional Budget Office (CBO) and others--show that 
over the long term we face a large and growing structural deficit due 
primarily to known demographic trends and rising health care costs. 
Continuing on this unsustainable fiscal path will gradually erode, if 
not suddenly damage, our economy, our standard of living, and 
ultimately our national security. Our current path also will 
increasingly constrain our ability to address emerging and unexpected 
budgetary needs.

Regardless of the assumptions used, all simulations indicate that the 
problem is too big to be solved by economic growth alone or by making 
modest changes to existing spending and tax policies. Nothing less than 
a fundamental reexamination of all major spending and tax policies and 
priorities is needed. This reexamination should also involve a national 
discussion about what Americans want from their government and how much 
they are willing to pay for those things. This discussion will not be 
easy, but it must take place.

In fiscal year 2004 alone, the nation's fiscal imbalance grew 
dramatically, primarily due to enactment of the new Medicare 
prescription drug benefit, which added $8.1 trillion to the outstanding 
commitments and obligations of the U.S. government. The near-term 
deficits also reflected higher defense, homeland security, and overall 
discretionary spending which exceeded growth in the economy, as well as 
revenues which have fallen below historical averages due to policy 
decisions and other economic and technical factors.

While the nation's long-term fiscal imbalance grew significantly, the 
retirement of the baby boom generation has come closer to becoming a 
reality. In fact, the cost implications of the baby boom generation's 
retirement have already become a factor in CBO's baseline projections 
and will only intensify as the boomers age. According to CBO, total 
federal spending for Social Security, Medicare, and Medicaid is 
projected to grow by about 25 percent over the next 10 years--from 8.4 
percent of gross domestic product (GDP) in 2004 to 10.4 percent in 
2015. Given these and other factors, it is clear that the nation's 
current fiscal path is unsustainable and that tough choices will be 
necessary in order to address the growing imbalance.

There are different ways to describe the magnitude of Social Security's 
long-term financing challenge, but they all show a need for program 
reform sooner rather than later. A case can be made for a range of 
different measures, as well as different time horizons. For instance, 
the shortfall can be measured in present value, as a percentage of GDP, 
or as a percentage of taxable payroll. The Social Security 
Administration (SSA) has made projections of the Social Security 
shortfall using different time horizons. (See table 1.)

Table 1: Different Measures, Same Challenge:

Projection Horizon: 75 year; 
SSA's Projections of Unfunded OASDI Obligations: Present value: $3.7 
Trillion; 
SSA's Projections of Unfunded OASDI Obligations: Percent of GDP: 0.7%; 
SSA's Projections of Unfunded OASDI Obligations: Percent of payroll: 
1.8%.

Projection Horizon: Infinite horizon; 
SSA's Projections of Unfunded OASDI Obligations: Present value: $10.4 
Trillion; 
SSA's Projections of Unfunded OASDI Obligations: Percent of GDP: 1.2%; 
SSA's Projections of Unfunded OASDI Obligations: Percent of payroll: 
3.5%.

Source: SSA.

Note: Data from Social Security Administration, The 2004 Annual Report 
of the Board of Trustees of the Federal Old-Age and Survivors Insurance 
and Disability Insurance Trust Fund (Washington, D.C., March 2004).

[End of table]

While estimates vary due to different horizons, both identify the same 
long-term challenge: The Social Security system is unsustainable in the 
long run. Taking action soon on Social Security would not only make the 
necessary action less dramatic than if we wait but would also promote 
increased budgetary flexibility in the future and stronger economic 
growth.

Although the Trustees' 2004 intermediate estimates project that the 
combined Social Security Trust Funds will be solvent until 
2042,[Footnote 4] within the next few years, Social Security spending 
will begin to put pressure on the rest of the federal budget. (See 
table 2.) Under the Trustees' 2004 intermediate estimates, Social 
Security's cash surplus--the difference between program tax income and 
the costs of paying scheduled benefits--will begin a permanent decline 
in 2008. (See fig. 1.) To finance the same level of federal spending as 
in the previous year, additional revenues and/or increased borrowing 
will be needed in each subsequent year.

Table 2: Key Dates Highlight Long Term Challenges of the Social 
Security System:

Date: 2008; 
Event: Social Security cash surplus begins to decline.

Date: 2018; 
Event: Annual benefit costs exceed cash revenue from taxes.

Date: 2028; 
Event: Trust fund ceases to grow because even taxes plus interest fall 
short of benefits.

Date: 2042 (SSA); 2052 (CBO); 
Event: Trust fund exhausted, annual revenues sufficient to pay about 
73% - 81% of promised benefits.

Sources: SSA and CBO.

Note: Data from Social Security Administration, The 2004 Annual Report 
of the Board of Trustees of the Federal Old-Age and Survivors Insurance 
and Disability Insurance Trust Funds (Washington, D.C., March 2004) and 
Congressional Budget Office, The Outlook for Social Security: Potential 
Range of Social Security Outlays and Revenues Under Current Law 
(Washington, D.C., June 2004).

[End of table]

Figure 1: Social Security and Medicare's Hospital Insurance Trust Funds 
Face Cash Deficits:

[See PDF for image] 

Note: Projections based on the intermediate assumptions of the 2004 
Trustees' Reports.

[End of figure]

By 2018,[Footnote 5] Social Security's cash income (tax revenue) is 
projected to fall below program expenses. At that time, Social Security 
will join Medicare's Hospital Insurance Trust Fund, whose outlays 
exceeded cash revenues in 2004, as a net claimant on the rest of the 
federal budget. The combined OASDI Trust Funds will begin drawing on 
the Treasury to cover the cash shortfall. At this point, Treasury will 
need to obtain cash for those redeemed securities either through 
increased taxes, and/or spending cuts, and/or more borrowing from the 
public than would have been the case had Social Security's cash flow 
remained positive.

Today Social Security spending exceeds federal spending for Medicare 
and Medicaid, but that will change. While Social Security is expected 
to grow about 5.6 percent per year on average over the next 10 years, 
Medicare and Medicaid combined are expected to grow at 8.5 percent per 
year. As a result, CBO's baseline projects Medicare and Medicaid 
spending will be about 30 percent higher than Social Security in 2015. 
According to the Social Security and Medicare trustees, Social Security 
will grow from 4.3 percent of GDP today to 6.6 percent in 2075, and 
Medicare's burden on the economy will quintuple--from 2.7 percent to 
13.3 percent of the economy.

GAO's long-term simulations illustrate the magnitude of the fiscal 
challenges associated with an aging society and the significance of the 
related challenges the government will be called upon to address. 
Figures 2 and 3 present these simulations under two different sets of 
assumptions. In figure 2, we begin with CBO's January baseline, 
constructed according to the statutory requirements for that 
baseline.[Footnote 6] Consistent with these requirements, 
discretionary spending is assumed to grow with inflation for the first 
10 years and tax cuts scheduled to expire are assumed to expire. After 
2015, discretionary spending is assumed to grow with the economy, and 
revenue is held constant as a share of GDP at the 2015 level. In figure 
3 two assumptions are changed: discretionary spending is assumed to 
grow with the economy after 2005 rather than merely with inflation and 
the tax cuts are extended. For both simulations Social Security and 
Medicare spending is based on the 2004 Trustees' intermediate 
projections, and we assume that benefits continue to be paid in full 
after the trust funds are exhausted. Medicaid spending is based on 
CBO's December 2003 long-term projections under mid-range assumptions.

Figure 2: Composition of Spending as a Share of Gross Domestic Product 
(GDP) under Baseline Extended:

[See PDF for image] 

Notes: In addition to the expiration of tax cuts, revenue as a share of 
GDP increases through 2015 due to (1) real bracket creep, (2) more 
taxpayers becoming subject to the AMT, and (3) increased revenue from 
tax-deferred retirement accounts. After 2015, revenue as a share of GDP 
is held constant.

[End of figure]

Figure 3: Composition of Spending as a Share of GDP Assuming 
Discretionary Spending Grows with GDP after 2005 and All Expiring Tax 
Provisions Are Extended:

[See PDF for image] 

Notes: Although expiring tax provisions are extended, revenue as a 
share of GDP increases through 2015 due to (1) real bracket creep, (2) 
more taxpayers becoming subject to the AMT, and (3) increased revenue 
from tax-deferred retirement accounts. After 2015, revenue as a share 
of GDP is held constant.

[End of figure] 

Both these simulations illustrate that, absent policy changes, the 
growth in spending on federal retirement and health entitlements will 
encumber an escalating share of the government's resources. Indeed, 
when we assume that recent tax reductions are made permanent and 
discretionary spending keeps pace with the economy, our long-term 
simulations suggest that by 2040 federal revenues may be adequate to 
pay little more than interest on the federal debt. Neither slowing the 
growth in discretionary spending nor allowing the tax provisions to 
expire--nor both together--would eliminate the imbalance. Although 
revenues will be part of the debate about our fiscal future, the 
failure to reform Social Security, Medicare, Medicaid, and other 
drivers of the long-term fiscal gap would require at least a doubling 
of taxes--and that seems implausible. Accordingly, substantive reform 
of Social Security and our major health programs remains critical to 
recapturing our future fiscal flexibility.

Although considerable uncertainty surrounds long-term budget 
projections, we know two things for certain: the population is aging 
and the baby boom generation is approaching retirement age. The aging 
population and rising health care spending will have significant 
implications not only for the budget but also for the economy as a 
whole. Figure 4 shows the total future draw on the economy represented 
by Social Security, Medicare, and Medicaid. Under the 2004 Trustees' 
intermediate estimates and CBO's long-term Medicaid estimates, spending 
for these entitlement programs combined will grow to 15.6 percent of 
GDP in 2030 from today's 8.5 percent. It is clear that, taken together, 
Social Security, Medicare, and Medicaid represent an unsustainable 
burden on future generations.

Figure 4: Social Security, Medicare, and Medicaid Spending as a 
Percentage of GDP:

[See PDF for image] 

Note: Social Security and Medicare projections based on the 
intermediate assumptions of the 2004 Trustees' Reports. Medicaid 
projections based on CBO's January 2005 short-term Medicaid estimates 
and CBO's December 2003 long-term Medicaid projections under mid-range 
assumptions.

[End of figure] 

The government can help ease future fiscal burdens through spending 
reductions or revenue actions that reduce debt held by the public, 
thereby saving for the future and enhancing the pool of economic 
resources available for private investment and long-term growth. 
Economic growth can help, but given the size of our projected fiscal 
gap we will not be able to simply grow our way out of the problem. 
Closing the current long-term fiscal gap would require sustained 
economic growth far beyond that experienced in U.S. economic history 
since World War II. Tough choices are inevitable, and the sooner we act 
the better.

Some of the benefits of early action--and the costs of delay--can be 
illustrated using the 2004 Social Security Trustees' intermediate 
projections. Figure 5 compares what it would take to keep Social 
Security solvent through 2078 by either raising payroll taxes or 
reducing benefits. If we did nothing until 2042--the year SSA estimates 
the Trust Funds will be exhausted--achieving actuarial balance would 
require changes in benefits of 30 percent or changes in taxes of 43 
percent. As figure 5 shows, earlier action shrinks the size of the 
necessary adjustment.

Figure 5: Size of Action Needed to Achieve Social Security Solvency:

[See PDF for image] 

Note: This is based on the intermediate assumptions of the 2004 Social 
Security Trustees Report. The benefit adjustments in this graph 
represent a one-time, permanent change to all existing and future 
benefits beginning in the first year indicated. Estimates cover the 
time period from January 1st of the first year to December 31, 2078.

[End of figure] 

Both sustainability concerns and solvency considerations drive us to 
act sooner rather than later. Trust Fund exhaustion may be nearly 40 
years away, but the squeeze on the federal budget will begin as the 
baby boom generation begins to retire. Actions taken today can ease 
both these pressures and the pain of future actions. Acting sooner 
rather than later also provides a more reasonable planning horizon for 
future retirees.

Demographic Trends Drive Both the Long-term Fiscal Outlook and Social 
Security's Financing Challenge:

The Social Security program's situation is but one symptom of larger 
demographic trends that will have broad and profound effects on our 
nation's future in other ways as well. As you are aware, Social 
Security has always been a largely pay-as-you-go system. This means 
that the system's financial condition is directly affected by the 
relative size of the populations of covered workers and beneficiaries. 
Historically, this relationship has been favorable to the system's 
financial condition. Now, however, people are living longer and 
spending more time in retirement.

As shown in figure 6, the U.S. elderly dependency ratio is expected to 
continue to increase.[Footnote 7]The proportion of the elderly 
population relative to the working-age population in the U.S. rose from 
13 percent in 1950 to 19 percent in 2000. By 2050, there is projected 
to be almost 1 elderly dependent for every 3 people of working age--a 
ratio of 32 percent. Additionally, the average life expectancy of males 
at birth has increased from 66.6 in 1960 to 74.3 in 2000, with females 
at birth experiencing a rise from 73.1 to 79.7 over the same period. As 
general life expectancy has increased in the United States, there has 
also been an increase in the number of years spent in retirement. 
Improvements in life expectancy have extended the average amount of 
time spent by workers in retirement from 11.5 years in 1950 to 18 years 
for the average male worker as of 2003.

Figure 6: U.S. Elderly Dependency Ratio Is Expected to Continue to 
Increase:

[See PDF for image] 

[End of figure] 

A falling fertility rate is the other principal factor underlying the 
growth in the elderly's share of the population. In the 1960s, the 
fertility rate, which is the average number of children that would be 
born to women during their childbearing years, was an average of 3 
children per woman. Today it is a little over 2, and by 2030 it is 
expected to fall to 1.95--a rate that is below what it takes to 
maintain a stable population. Taken together, these trends threaten the 
financial solvency and sustainability of Social Security.

The combination of these factors means that annual labor force growth 
will begin to slow after 2010 and by 2025 is expected to be less than a 
fifth of what it is today. (See fig. 7.) Relatively fewer workers will 
be available to produce the goods and services that all will consume. 
Without a major increase in productivity or increases in immigration, 
low labor force growth will lead to slower growth in the economy and to 
slower growth of federal revenues. This in turn will only accentuate 
the overall pressure on the federal budget.

Figure 7: Labor Force Growth Is Expected to Slow Significantly:

[See PDF for image] 

Note: Percentage change is calculated as a centered 5-yr. moving 
average of projections based on the intermediate assumptions of the 
2004 Trustees Reports.

[End of figure] 

The aging of the labor force and the reduced growth in the number of 
workers will have important implications for the size and composition 
of the labor force, as well as the characteristics of many jobs, 
throughout the 21st century. The U.S. workforce of the 21st century 
will be facing a very different set of opportunities and challenges 
than that of previous generations.

Increased investment could increase the productivity of workers and 
spur economic growth. However, increasing investment depends on 
national saving, which remains at historically low levels. 
Historically, the most direct way for the federal government to 
increase saving has been to reduce the deficit (or run a surplus). 
Although the government may try to increase personal saving, results of 
these efforts have been mixed. For example, even with the preferential 
tax treatment granted since the 1970s to encourage retirement saving, 
the personal saving rate has steadily declined. Even if economic growth 
increases, the structure of retirement programs and historical 
experience in health care cost growth suggest that higher economic 
growth results in a generally commensurate growth in spending for these 
programs in the long term.[Footnote 8]

In recent years, personal saving by households has reached record lows 
while at the same time the federal budget deficit has climbed. (See 
fig. 8.) Accordingly, national saving has diminished but the economy 
has continued to grow in part because more and better investments were 
made. That is, each dollar saved bought more investment goods and a 
greater share of saving was invested in highly productive information 
technology. The economy has also continued to grow because the United 
States was able to invest more than it saved by borrowing abroad, that 
is, by running a current account deficit. However, a portion of the 
income generated by foreign-owned assets in the United States must be 
paid to foreign lenders. National saving is the only way a country can 
have its capital and own it too.

Figure 8: Personal Saving Rate Has Steadily Declined:

[See PDF for image] 

[End of figure] 

In general, saving involves trading off consumption today for greater 
consumption tomorrow. Our budget decisions today will have important 
consequences for the living standards of future generations. The 
financial burdens facing the smaller cohort of future workers in an 
aging society would most certainly be lessened if the economic pie were 
enlarged. This is no easy challenge, but in a very real sense, our 
fiscal decisions affect the longer-term economy through their effects 
on national saving.

The persistent U.S. current account deficits of recent years have 
translated into a rising level of indebtedness to other countries. 
However, many other nations currently financing investment in the 
United States also will face aging populations and declining national 
saving, so relying on foreign savings to finance a large share of U.S. 
domestic investment or federal borrowing is not a viable strategy in 
the long run.

Health Care Is a Larger and More Difficult Challenge Than Social 
Security:

As figure 4 showed, over the long term Medicare and Medicaid will 
dominate the federal government's future fiscal outlook. Medicare 
growth rates reflect not only a burgeoning beneficiary population but 
also the escalation of health care costs at rates well exceeding 
general rates of inflation. Health care generally presents not only a 
much greater but a more complex challenge than Social Security. The 
structural changes needed to address health care cost growth will take 
time to develop, and the process of reforming health care is likely to 
be an incremental one.

While the long-term fiscal challenge cannot be successfully addressed 
without addressing Medicare and Medicaid, federal health spending 
trends should not be viewed in isolation from the health care system as 
a whole. For example, Medicare and Medicaid cannot grow over the long 
term at a slower rate than cost in the rest of the health care system 
without resulting in a two-tier health care system. This, for example, 
could squeeze providers who then in turn might seek to recoup costs 
from other payers elsewhere in the health care system. Rather, in order 
to address the long-term fiscal challenge, it will be necessary to find 
approaches that deal with health care cost growth in the overall health 
care system.

Although health care spending is the largest driver of the long-term 
fiscal outlook, this does not mean that Social Security reform should 
be postponed until after health is addressed. On the contrary, it 
argues for moving ahead on Social Security now. The outlines of Social 
Security reform have already been articulated in many Social Security 
reform proposals. These approaches and the specific elements of reform 
are well known and have been the subject of many analyses, including 
GAO reports and testimonies. Reform approaches already put forward can 
serve as a starting point for deliberations.

Considerations In Assessing Reform Options:

As important as financial stability may be for Social Security, it 
cannot be the only consideration. As a former public trustee of Social 
Security and Medicare, I am well aware of the central role these 
programs play in the lives of millions of Americans. Social Security 
remains the foundation of the nation's retirement system. It is also 
much more than just a retirement program; it pays benefits to disabled 
workers and their dependents, spouses and children of retired workers, 
and survivors of deceased workers. In 2004, Social Security paid almost 
$493 billion in benefits to more than 47 million people. Since its 
inception, the program has successfully reduced poverty among the 
elderly. In 1959, 35 percent of the elderly were poor. In 2000, about 8 
percent of beneficiaries aged 65 or older were poor, and 48 percent 
would have been poor without Social Security. It is precisely because 
the program is so deeply woven into the fabric of our nation that any 
proposed reform must consider the program in its entirety, rather than 
one aspect alone. To assist policymakers, GAO has developed a broad 
framework for evaluating reform proposals that considers not only 
solvency but other aspects of the program as well. Our criteria aim to 
balance financial and economic considerations with benefit adequacy and 
equity issues and the administrative challenges associated with various 
proposals.

GAO Framework For Evaluating Reform Proposals:

The analytic framework GAO has developed to assess proposals comprises 
three basic criteria:

* Financing Sustainable Solvency--the extent to which a proposal 
achieves sustainable solvency and how it would affect the economy and 
the federal budget. Our sustainable solvency standard encompasses 
several different ways of looking at the Social Security program's 
financing needs. While a 75-year actuarial balance has generally been 
used in evaluating the long-term financial outlook of the Social 
Security program and reform proposals, it is not sufficient in gauging 
the program's solvency after the 75th year. For example, under the 
trustees' intermediate assumptions, each year the 75-year actuarial 
period changes, and a year with a surplus is replaced by a new 75th 
year that has a significant deficit. As a result, changes made to 
restore trust fund solvency only for the 75-year period can result in 
future actuarial imbalances almost immediately. Reform plans that lead 
to sustainable solvency would be those that consider the broader issues 
of fiscal sustainability and affordability over the long term. 
Specifically, a standard of sustainable solvency also involves looking 
at (1) the balance between program income and costs beyond the 75th 
year and (2) the share of the budget and economy consumed by Social 
Security spending.

* Balancing Adequacy and Equity--the relative balance struck between 
the goals of individual equity and income adequacy. The current Social 
Security system's benefit structure attempts to strike a balance 
between these two goals. From the beginning, Social Security benefits 
were set in a way that focused especially on replacing some portion of 
workers' preretirement earnings. Over time other changes were made that 
were intended to enhance the program's role in helping ensure adequate 
incomes. Retirement income adequacy, therefore, is addressed in part 
through the program's progressive benefit structure, providing 
proportionately larger benefits to lower earners and certain household 
types, such as those with dependents. Individual equity refers to the 
relationship between contributions made and benefits received. This can 
be thought of as the rate of return on individual contributions. 
Balancing these seemingly conflicting objectives through the political 
process has resulted in the design of the current Social Security 
program and should still be taken into account in any proposed reforms.

* Implementing and Administering Proposed Reforms--how readily a 
proposal could be implemented, administered, and explained to the 
public. Program complexity makes implementation and administration both 
more difficult and harder to explain. Some degree of implementation and 
administrative complexity arises in virtually all proposed changes to 
Social Security, even those that make incremental changes in the 
already existing structure. Although these issues may appear technical 
or routine on the surface, they are important issues because they have 
the potential to delay--if not derail--reform if they are not 
considered early enough for planning purposes. Moreover, issues such as 
feasibility and cost can, and should, influence policy choices. 
Continued public acceptance of and confidence in the Social Security 
program require that any reforms and their implications for benefits be 
well understood. This means that the American people must understand 
why change is necessary, what the reforms are, why they are needed, how 
they are to be implemented and administered, and how they will affect 
their own retirement income. All reform proposals will require some 
additional outreach to the public so that future beneficiaries can 
adjust their retirement planning accordingly. The more transparent the 
implementation and administration of reform, and the more carefully 
such reform is phased in, the more likely it will be understood and 
accepted by the American people.

The weight that different policymakers place on different criteria will 
vary, depending on how they value different attributes. For example, if 
offering individual choice and control is less important than 
maintaining replacement rates for low-income workers, then a reform 
proposal emphasizing adequacy considerations might be preferred. As 
they fashion a comprehensive proposal, however, policymakers will 
ultimately have to balance the relative importance they place on each 
of these criteria. As we have noted in the past before this committee 
and elsewhere, a comprehensive evaluation is needed that considers a 
range of effects together. Focusing on comprehensive packages of 
reforms will enable us to foster credibility and acceptance. This will 
help us avoid getting mired in the details and losing sight of 
important interactive effects. It will help build the bridges necessary 
to achieve consensus.

Reform's Potential Effects on the Social Security Program:

A variety of proposals have been offered to address Social Security's 
financial problems. Many proposals contain reforms that would alter 
benefits or revenues within the structure of the current defined 
benefits system. Some would reduce benefits by modifying the benefit 
formula (such as increasing the number of years used to calculate 
benefits or using price indexing instead of wage indexing), reduce 
cost-of-living adjustments (COLA), raise the normal and/or early 
retirement ages, or revise dependent benefits. Some of the proposals 
also include measures or benefit changes that seek to strengthen 
progressivity (e.g., replacement rates) in an effort to mitigate the 
effect on low-income workers. Others have proposed revenue increases, 
including raising the payroll tax or expanding the Social Security 
taxable wage base that finances the system; increasing the taxation of 
benefits; or covering those few remaining workers not currently 
required to participate in Social Security, such as older state and 
local government employees.

A number of proposals also seek to restructure the program through the 
creation of individual accounts. Under a system of individual accounts, 
workers would manage a portion of their own Social Security 
contributions to varying degrees. This would expose workers to a 
greater degree of risk in return for both greater individual choice in 
retirement investments and the possibility of a higher rate of return 
on contributions than available under current law. There are many 
different ways that an individual account system could be set up. For 
example, contributions to individual accounts could be mandatory or 
they could be voluntary. Proposals also differ in the manner in which 
accounts would be financed, the extent of choice and flexibility 
concerning investment options, the way in which benefits are paid out, 
and the way the accounts would interact with the existing Social 
Security program--individual accounts could serve either as an addition 
to or as a replacement for part of the current benefit structure.

In addition, the timing and impact of individual accounts on the 
solvency, sustainability, adequacy, equity, net savings, and rate of 
return associated with the Social Security system varies depending on 
the structure of the total reform package. Individual accounts by 
themselves will not lead the system to sustainable solvency. Achieving 
sustainable solvency requires more revenue, lower benefits, or both. 
Furthermore, incorporating a system of individual accounts may involve 
significant transition costs. These costs come about because the Social 
Security system would have to continue paying out benefits to current 
and near-term retirees concurrently with establishing new individual 
accounts.

Individual accounts can contribute to sustainability as they could 
provide a mechanism to prefund retirement benefits that would be immune 
to demographic booms and busts. However, if such accounts are funded 
through borrowing, no such prefunding is achieved. An additional 
important consideration in adopting a reform package that contains 
individual accounts would be the level of benefit adequacy achieved by 
the reform. To the extent that benefits are not adequate, it may result 
in the government eventually providing additional revenues to make up 
the difference.

Also, some degree of implementation and administrative complexity 
arises in virtually all proposed changes to Social Security. The 
greatest potential implementation and administrative challenges are 
associated with proposals that would create individual accounts. These 
include, for example, issues concerning the management of the 
information and money flow needed to maintain such a system, the degree 
of choice and flexibility individuals would have over investment 
options and access to their accounts, investment education and 
transitional efforts, and the mechanisms that would be used to pay out 
benefits upon retirement. The federal Thrift Savings Plan (TSP) could 
serve as a model for providing a limited amount of options that reduce 
risk and administrative costs while still providing some degree of 
choice. However, a system of accounts that spans the entire national 
workforce and millions of employers would be significantly larger and 
more complex than TSP or any other system we have in place today.

Another important consideration for Social Security reform is assessing 
a proposal's effect on national saving. Individual account proposals 
that fund accounts through redirection of payroll taxes or general 
revenue do not increase national saving on a first order basis. The 
redirection of payroll taxes or general revenue reduces government 
saving by the same amount that the individual accounts increase private 
saving. Beyond these first order effects, the actual net effect of a 
proposal on national saving is difficult to estimate due to 
uncertainties in predicting changes in future spending and revenue 
policies of the government as well as changes in the saving behavior of 
private households and individuals. For example, the lower surpluses 
and higher deficits that result from redirecting payroll taxes to 
individual accounts could lead to changes in federal fiscal policy that 
would increase national saving. On the other hand, households may 
respond by reducing their other saving in response to the creation of 
individual accounts. No expert consensus exists on how Social Security 
reform proposals would affect the saving behavior of private households 
and businesses.

Finally, the effort to reform Social Security is occurring as our 
nation's private pension system is also facing serious challenges. Only 
about half of the private sector workforce is covered by a pension 
plan. A number of large underfunded traditional defined benefit plans-
-plans where the employer bears the risk of investment--have been 
terminated by bankrupt firms, including household names like Bethlehem 
Steel, US Airways, and Polaroid. These terminations have resulted in 
thousands of workers losing promised benefits and have saddled the 
Pension Benefit Guaranty Corporation, the government corporation that 
partially insures certain defined benefit pension benefits, with 
billions of dollars in liabilities that threaten its long-term 
solvency. Meanwhile, the number of traditional defined benefit pension 
plans continues to decline as employers increasingly offer workers 
defined contribution plans like 401(k) plans where, like individual 
accounts, workers face the potential of both greater return and greater 
risk. These challenges serve to reinforce the imperative to place 
Social Security on a sound financial footing which provides a 
foundation of certain and secure retirement income.

Regardless of what type of Social Security reform package is adopted, 
continued confidence in the Social Security program is essential. This 
means that the American people must understand why change is necessary, 
what the reforms are, why they are needed, how they are to be 
implemented and administered, and how they will affect their own 
retirement income. All reform proposals will require some additional 
outreach to the public so that future beneficiaries can adjust their 
retirement planning accordingly. The more transparent the 
implementation and administration of reform, and the more carefully 
such reform is phased in, the more likely it will be understood and 
accepted by the American people.

Conclusions:

Social Security does not face an immediate crisis but it does face a 
large and growing financial problem. In addition, our Social Security 
challenge is only part of a much broader fiscal challenge that 
includes, among other things, the need to reform Medicare, Medicaid, 
and our overall health care system.

Today we have an opportunity to address Social Security as a first step 
toward improving the nation's long-term fiscal outlook. Steps to reform 
our federal health care system are likely to be much more difficult. 
They are also likely to require a series of incremental actions over an 
extended period of time. As I have said before, the future 
sustainability of programs is the key issue policy makers should 
address--i.e., the capacity of the economy and budget to afford the 
commitment over time. Absent substantive reform, these important 
federal programs will not be sustainable. Furthermore, absent reform, 
younger workers will face dramatic benefit reductions or tax increases 
that will grow over time.

Many retirees and near retirees fear cuts that would affect them in the 
immediate future while young people believe they will get little or no 
Social Security benefits in the longer term. I believe that it is 
possible to reform Social Security in a way that will ensure the 
program's solvency, sustainability, and security while exceeding the 
expectations of all generations of Americans.

(450387):

FOOTNOTES

[1] In this statement, Social Security refers to the Old-Age and 
Survivors Insurance and Disability Insurance (OASDI) program.

[2] GAO, Budget Issues: Long-Term Fiscal Challenges, GAO-02-467T 
(Washington, D.C.: Feb. 27, 2002); Social Security: Long-Term Financing 
Shortfall Drives Need for Reform, GAO-02-845T (Washington, D.C.: June 
19, 2002); and Social Security: Long-Term Challenges Warrant Early 
Action, GAO-05-303T (Washington, D.C.: Feb. 3, 2005). 

[3] Saving Our Nation's Future: An Intergovernmental Challenge, Outlook 
2005 Conference, The National Press Club (Washington D.C.: Feb. 2, 
2005). This product can be found on GAO's web site, www.gao.gov.

[4] Separately, the Disability Insurance (DI) fund is projected to be 
exhausted in 2029 and the Old-Age and Survivors' Insurance (OASI) fund 
in 2044. Using slightly different economic assumptions and model 
specifications, CBO estimated the combined Social Security trust fund 
will be solvent until 2052. See Congressional Budget Office, The 
Outlook for Social Security (Washington, D.C.: June 2004) and Updated 
Long-Term Projections for Social Security (Washington, D.C.: January 
2005).

[5] CBO estimates that this will occur in 2020. See CBO's Updated Long-
Term Projections for Social Security (January 2005).

[6] The Congressional Budget Office, The Budget and Economic Outlook: 
Fiscal Years 2006 to 2015, (Washington, D.C.: January 2005).

[7] The elderly dependency ratio is the ratio of the population aged 65 
years or over to the population aged 15 to 64.

[8] Initial Social Security benefits are indexed to nominal wage growth 
resulting in higher benefits over time.